R9941 Tax Complexity, Reform In George Mason 1994

User Manual: R9941

Open the PDF directly: View PDF PDF.
Page Count: 42

319
r9941
TAX COMPLEXITY, REFORM,
AND THE ILLUSIONS
TAX SIMPLIFICATION
Sheldon
D. Pollack*
OF
..[N]o one
understands
the Income
Tax Law [the
Revenue
Act of 1913]
ex.
cept
persons who have
not sufficient
intelligence
to understand
the
questions
that arise
under
it."
Senator
Elihu
Root
of New York (1913)
"simplicity in modern
taxation
is a problem of basic architectural
design.
Present
legislation
is
insufferably
complicated
and
nearly
unintelligible.
If it is
not simplified,
half of the population
may have
to become
tax lawyers
and
tax
accountants."
Henry C. Simons,
Federal
Tax Reform (1950)
..The
complexity
of our code
in the main is not there because
of some
mis-
chief.
Most of it is there
in the effort
to do more
perfect
justice'"
Senator Russell Long, Former Chairman, Senate Finance
Committee
lNrRooucuoN
Inasmuch
as only the rudimentary
Structure
of a taxing scheme
was laid out
in the
first
income
tax
law,
the
Revenue
Act of 1913,r
the
many
details
required
to give
concrete
meaning
to the statute
were left
to be filled
in over
subsequent
decades.
Accordingly,
the
newly
imposed
federal
income
tax progressively became
more
complicated
during its
first decades
as
it evolved
through
a process of gradual
and
incremental
adjustments
to the original
tax laws.
The development
of the tax laws
entered
a second
phase
when the
income
tax was radically
transformed
into a "mass
tax" during
World War II' In the post-War
era'
espe-
* Assistant
Professor,
College
of Busincss
and
Economics,
University
of Delaware;
Univer-
sitV
of Rochester,
B.A., 19?4;
Cornell University,
Ph.D.,
1980;
University
of Pennsylvania,
l9E6'
J.D. The author
wishes to thank Professor
Dcborah
H. Schenk
of New York University
School
of
Law for her helpful
comments
on an earlier
draft of this article
and
the Gowen
Fellowship
Fund
of the Law School
of the University
of Pennsylvania
for its generous financial
support'
' Pub.
L. No.63'16,
ch. l6' 38
Stat.
l14' 166-81
320 Gro. MnsoN
lNnrp. L. Rrv. lYol.2:2
cially during the 1970s
and 1980s,
the level
of complexity of the in-
come tax
increased dramatically.'
As reflected by the sheer number
of
provisions
of the federal income tax, there
was
a virtual explosion in
the complexity of the tax code in the post-War period.s
In light of this dramatic
increase
in complexity of the federal
in-
come
tax, there is a tendency
to equate
tax reform
with tax "simplifica-
tion."a
Indeed,
tax simplification
has emerged
as
one
of the perennial
themes in the academic
tax literature.6
Some
reform
efforts have been
directed at specific
provisions
of the tax code and
regulations.
Other
proposals
amount
to little more
than broad
pleas
for general
simplifica.
tion and appear to be
politically
motivated. For instance,
House
Ways
and Means Chairman Rostenkowski
and then Finance
Committee
Chairman Bentsen
picked
up on the theme of tax simplification
and
introduced
a package
of proposals
in 1991.6 These
proposed provisions
were
mostly window
dressing
and
focused
on simplification
of reporting
2 In a recent interview,
Professor Martin Ginsburg recounts that even under the Internal
Revenue Code of 1954 there were
only a few statutory
and
regulatory "monsters"
for tax lawyers
to struggle
to master.
Under the 1986 tax code, the monsters now
seem
to dominate
the
playing
field. ,See Martin D. Ginsburg, Interview With Professor
Martin D. Ginsburg, l2 ABA SrcrroN
Or TrxrrroN NEwslnrrEn, Fall 1992, at 6-12.
" The Internal Revenue Code
and
Treasury
regulations
were
first
published
in l9l3 by Com-
merce Clearing House, Inc. (CCH) in a single
volume
consisting of little more
than
400
pages.
This remained
the case
through World War II. Presently,
the tax code and
regulations
take up a
total of eight
volumes
and over 36,000
pages.
There has been
a comparable explosion of "law" in
other
policy
areas as
well. For
instance, Title II of the Social Security Act of 1935
was
only
four
pages
long
when
enacted,
grew
to 50
pages
by 1950, and exploded to 200
pages
in the 1970s. This
did not even include new
sections of the statute,
such as medicare. Mlnrun Dnnrurcr, Acrxcy
UNoEn Srnrss: Tur Soctlr Srcunrrv AoMrNrsrnerroN
rN AMERTcAN GovrnNlrrNr 201
(1990).
' See,
e.g., David
Brockway, The Process Behind
Successful
Tax Reform,3l Vrll. L. Rrv.
1803,
1803
(1986) ("True
tax
reform will not be
achieved unless there
is significant
simplification
of code
provisions.").
o See,
e.g.,
HrNny C. Srrr,roNs, Frnrul T,lx Rnnonu 28-30
(
1950); Paul McDaniel
, Federal
Income Tax Simplifcation: The Political Process,
34 Tlx L. Rrv. 27 (1978);
Federal
Income
Tax Simplifcarfon
(Charles
H. Gustafson
ed.,
1979);
U.S. Department of Treasury, Office of Tax
Analysis, Tax Reform
for Fairness, Simplicity, and Economic Growth: The Treasury Depart-
ment Report
to the
President,25Tt'x NorEs
873
(1984);
Joint Comm.
on
Tax'n,95th Cong., lst
Sess., Issues in Simplification
of the Income Tax Laws
(Comm.
Print 1977);
Sidney L Roberts,
Simplifcation Symposium,
34 Tlx L. Rnv. 5 (1978);
Boris I. Bittker, Iar Reform and Tax
Simplification,29
U. Mlrrrlt L. Rnv. I (1974);
Deborah H. Schenk, Simplifcationfor Individual
Taxpayers: Problems
and Proposals,45
Tu L. REv.
l2l (1989);
Charles A. Mclure, Jt., The
Budget Process and Tax Simplifcation/Complication,45
Tex L. REv. 25 (1989).
6 Trx Srrrlpr-rrrcArroN
Acr Or 1991,
S.
Doc. No. 1394, H.R. Doc. No.2777,102d Cong.,
lst Sess.
(1991).
r
e94l IrlusroNs or T,c,x StvtpLIrIclttoN
on tax returns.
Even
former
IRS Commissioner
Goldberg
promoted
tax
simplification,
but he left unstated
precisely
what that meant.T
These and many other
proposals
for simplification
make
for good
press,
but do not address
the fundamental
causes
behind the
rise in tax
complexity.
Few of the
reformers
posturing
for simplification
of the tax
laws recognize the inherent difficulties
in any attempt
to simplify the
code.
Some
of the excess
complexity is attributable to efforts by policy-
makers to accomplish too much through the tax laws. In other in-
stances,
the
great
complexities
of the tax laws
are attributable
to prior
reforms enacted
in the
pursuit
of ever
greater purity
in the
tax laws. As
Senator
Russell
Long
once
quipped: "The complexity of our
code in the
main is not there because
of some
mischief. Most of it is there
in the
effort to do
more
perfect
justice."s
Long's
proposition
is worth consider-
ing, even if it lacks a certain critical
perspective
as evidenced
by Long's
own
willingness to enact
countless special
provisions
for the sole benefit
of his constituent
gas
and oil industries.
The causes behind the enormous complexity
in the
tax laws cannot
be reduced to any single
factor. Thus, open-ended calls
for "simplifica-
tion" to cure
the problem
of complexity
ring almost
as hollow as the
claim that tax complexity
is attributable
to the search
for "more
per-
fect
justice"
in the tax code-both claims
are overly simplistic.
In order
to intelligently discuss tax simplification, it is necessary to consider
why
the tax laws
became
overly complex in past
decades,
and to recognize
the infirmity of overly complex tax
laws. Because
tax lawyers earn their
livelihood from such complexities, many
will be reluctant to acknowl-
edge that there
is even a "problem"
at all.
To understand the adverse effects caused
by overly complex
tax
laws, one needs
first
to view
the federal
income tax from a broad
histor-
ical perspective
to place
the development of the tax system as a whole
within the context
of the
peculiar
structure
of American
political
insti-
tutions. Complexity
does not
enter the
tax code so much out
of malevo-
lence
as through
misguided reform
efforts
and excessive
demands
made
on tax laws
as the
vehicle for implementing
public
policy.
After under-
standing the broader context, it is possible
to identify those trends
in
recent
tax policymaking
that have
contributed
to this unfortunate
rise
7 See Lane Davenport,
Marianne
Evans, and Sean Ford, Goldberg
Still Beating
Drum For
Simplifcation;
Says /RS Budget is Way
Out of Balance,45
Tlx Norrs 1398
(1989).
E
TrrvrorHv J. CoNlrN Er ,',L., TlxrNc Csorcrs l4l (1990) (quoting
Senate
Finance Com-
mittee Heailngs onTax ReIorm Proposal,Volume 3,99th Cong.,2d Sess.,53
(1986) (statement
of Senator Russell
Long,
Former Chairman,
Senate Finance Committee)).
32r
322 Gro. MesoN INorp. L. Rnv, lYol.2:2
in tax complexity. The dilemma
that we
may very well
confront is that
the more
we
attempt to do through
the tax code-whether to achieve
a
"more perfect
justice" or implement
social economic
policies-the
more we end up making
the tax laws
even more
complex.
In doing so,
we
undermine the capacity
of the citizenf taxpayer to comprehend
the
legal obligations imposed under the regime
of the federal income
tax.
I. Coupr-Exrry
Iu Tnn FnorRnr
INcour Tnx Llws
A. The First Regime
of the Federal Income Tax
L The Original Tax System
Tax complexity is not a new
phenomenon,
although
it has reached
new heights in recent
decades. Since 1913, excessive complexity has
been a constant complaint
of taxpayers as
well as a favorite
theme of
reformers.e But to taxpayers and
counsel
who
have
grown
accustomed
to the statutory
excesses and
regulatory
quagmires
that seemed
to be-
come the norm in the 1980s,
the first income tax laws would
appear
relatively straight-forward
and uncomplicated.
For instance,
the original Form
1040
("Return
of Annual Net In-
come of Individuals"),
put in service
by the Bureau of Internal Reve-
nue in 1913, was
only three
pages
long, including
all its various
sched-
ules. It contained
only a single
page of instructions.lo The return
required
taxpayers to compute
and report
just two separate items,
"gross
income"
and total "general
deductions," and
provided
relatively
straightforward schedules for computing
each.
The
tax was
imposed on
net
income above
a $3,000
exemption
that
was
"received or accrued"
during the calendar
year,
thus employing
a hybrid method
of tax ac-
counting that borrowed
concepts from the cash and accrual methods
of
e Senator Elihu Root
of New York in l9l3 wrote
to a friend
who
had complained
about the
complexity
ofthe Revenue Act
of 19131 "I guess
you
will have
to
go
tojail. Ifthat is the result of
not understanding
the Income Tax Law I shall meet
you
there. . . . [F]or no one understands the
Income
Tax Law except
persons
who have
not sufficient intelligence
to understand the questions
that arise
under it." Quoted
in Henolo Dusnorr, THr UNrrno
Srerns Tlx Counr: AN Hrsron-
rcAL ANALYSTS l2 (1979).
ro
The 1993
Form 1040 is
just two pages
long,
but completing a complicated return may
require
the use of dozens of schedules and workshcets.
Form 1040
alone
is now accompanied by
almost fifty pages
of instructions
and
worksheets.
19941 IllusroNs or Tlx Slrr,rplrrrclrloN 323
tax accounting
so familiar in the modern code.rr
Essentially,
the 1913
income tax resurrected the short-lived
Civil War income tax as
well
as
the tax return used
fifty years
earlier.r2
Of course, many sophisticated
taxpayers
struggled
with the new
relatively
"simple" income tax form.re Notwithstanding that the l9l3
version of the federal income
tax was rather basic and
pristine
by to-
day's standards,
it already
was
perceived
by contemporaries as
far too
complicated to be understood by the average taxpayer.ra
The impact
and shock
felt by those confronting
the
new federal income tax law for
the first time
in 1913 may have
been even
worse than the bewilderment
felt today
by those
who make
their first acquaintance
with the
present
incarnation of the code. The sheer novelty of the
idea
of measuring
an
individual's
"income,"
as the new
tax required,
was
part of the reason
that the first income
tax laws would
have struck
individuals as
so com-
plex
and shocking.'6 Corporations
were
already familiar
with the notion
of computing income over a defined
accounting
period,
both for finan-
cial and tax purposes.
A federal
business
privilege
tax, similar in es-
sence to an income tax, had been
enacted
and sanctioned four years
prior
to the
ratification
of the Sixteenth Amendment.ro
But individuals
were
not
yet accustomed to measuring their human endeavors in terms
!r See I.R.C. $ aa6(c) (cash
and accrual methods as "permissible
methods" for computing
taxable income).
[All citations herein
are to the Internal
Revenue Code of 1986, as amended,
unless otherwise specified.]
'1 The tax return used
during the Civil War employed a similar framework. However,
the
return used in 1865 listed separately each source
of income
(specifically,
all "profits from any
trade, busincss, or vocation,"
rental income
from land or buildings,
"profits realized" from the
sale
of real property,
as
well as
interest
and dividends)
and allowed for "proper" deductions related
to
that source of income. Allowing for deductions
for losses sustained
on the sale
of real
estate,
interest
paid,
rent actually
paid
for the taxpayer's "homestead," and
an annual exemption for
$600
of salary for military
personnel,
the
tax
was imposed
upon
net income above a $600
personal
exemption.
For an account of the Civil War income tax, see Roy C. Burny & Grrpys C.
BlrxEv, TxE FeoEnll INcorrar T,c,x 2-8
(1940);
R,rNpolru E. Plul, T,rxlrroN rr rHr UNrtnn
Srrres 7-29
(1954).
rE
Indicative
of the fact that even the rudimentary tax return used
for the Civil War income
tax was
difficult for taxpayers to comprehend, Abraham Lincoln overpaid
his taxcs for 1864 by
$1,250,
a sizable amount by contcmporary standards of wealth. The incident is rccounted in
Drvro BunNnru, A Lnw Unro Irsrlr: Tsn IRS AND
rHE Asusr or Powrn 13
(1989).
t' See supra note 9.
r! Except for the brief experience with the Civil War income tax, a half ccntury
prior to the
l9l3 income
tax, citizens had only known
"indirect" forms of taxation.
Whilc transactions and
salcs
wcre subject to excise taxes and custom duties, the concept
of treating an individual as a
taxable economic unit was
relatively new, even in 1913,
!! The corporate business
privilege
tax
was
included
in the Payne-Aldrich
Tariff Act of I 909,
which was
imposed
"with respect to the
carrying
on or doing business"
of corporations. In Flint
v.
Stone Tracy Co.,220 U.S. 107
(l9ll), the U.S.
Supreme Court
held the tax to be a business
324 Gro. M,c,soN INorp.
L. Rnv [Yol,
2:2
of "net income."
Nor were
they
accustomed
to being
treated as discrete
economic s1i1s-"4seounting"
for their lives
as so many living
balance
sheets.
No matter how benign
the federal income
tax may appear by
today's standards, it represented
a milestone
in the development
of the
relationship between
the citizen
and
the state, transforming
the Ameri-
can
citizen
into a new category
of being-the Taxpayer.
Oddly enough,
the simplicity
of the first "bare-bones"
tax laws
may have actually contributed
to the
initial confusion
because
they
pro-
vided
taxpayers
with insufficient
guidance
as to what was
being
mea-
sured and how to measure
it. Successive
decades
of refinement
of the
statutes by lawmakers,
as
well
as the issuance
of interpretive
regula-
tions by the Treasury Department
under the authority
granted
by the
Revenue Act of 1928,17
somewhat
clarified
the meaning
of the basic
concepts of the federal income tax. These interpretations
brought
greater
certainty
and predictability
of outcome
to subsequent
genera-
tions of taxpayers, attorneys,
and tax experts.
2. Role
of the Federal
Courts
During the first decades
of the federal income
tax, the federal
courts and the Board
of Tax Appeals
contributed much flesh
and
blood
to the statutes.r8 Indeed,
the basic
nature
of the statutes and
the broad,
expansive language
used
by Congress
in drafting the initial revenue
laws made extensive
litigation inevitable.
Accordingly,
the federal
courts
were
drawn into a process
of articulating the meaning
of the
most basic and fundamental
concepts
of the income tax.
privilege
tax, and not
an income
tax
which would
have been
prohibited
under Article I, Section 9
of the
U.S. Constitution
as a "direct
tax."
r?
Pub. L. No. 78-562,
ch.
852, 45 Stat. 790,
791
(1928).
'6 The Board of Tax Appeals was established
under the Revenue
Act of 1924, ch. 234,
$ 900, 43 Stat. 336-38.
The Board was
technically
an "independent agency in the executive
branch," rather
than a
judicial body. In fact,
the Board
(which
was
renamed the Tax Court of the
United States in 1942) functioned
much
as a federal
trial court. In 1969,
in recognition of this,
Congress renamed
the body the "United States Tax Court" and
reclassified it as a so-called
"Arti-
cle I" federal
court (i.e.,
a judicial entity created
under
the authority
granted
to Congress in
Article I of the U.S. Constitution).
26 U.S.C.A.
g 7441
(Law.
Co-op.
1993). Nevertheless,
the
hybrid nature
of the
Tax Court still raises
problems.
See,
e.g., Freytag v. Comm'r,
lll S. Ct.
2631
(1991) (concerning
the
power
and
authority of the "special
trial
judges"
of the Tax
Court);
see
also Note: Special Trial Judges, The Tax Couil and the Appointments
Clause: Freytag v.
Comm'r,45 Tlx Lrwynn 497
(Winter
1992). For
a history
of the
U.S.
Tax Courr, see
Hrnolo
Durnorr, Tnr UNrrro Srerns Tex Counr: AN HrsroRtcAl
ANALysrs
(1979).
19941 lt-t ustoNs or Tlx Sttr,tpLtErcntlott
a. Defining
Income
The federal courts
were
called upon to define the most fundamen-
tal concept of the tax laws-what is "income"
for purposes
of the new
tax. The statutory definition of "income" provided
in the Revenue Act
of 1913 merely mirrored the language of the newly
ratified
Sixteenth
Amendment, which sanctioned the imposition of a "direct" tax on "in-
comes,
from whatever
source derived. Since
1913, the statutory
language
has remained virtually identical.
The present
definition is
found
in Section
6l(a) of the
Internal Revenue Code of 1986
and
sim-
ply states,
somewhat
tautologically, that:
"gross
income means all in-
come
from whatever
source derived. . . ."2o The broad net cast by the
statute
provides
considerable
room for debate
and disagreement
be-
tween
reasonable
persons
over
what
constitutes'(ins66s"-especially,
where
the source is a gift, bequest, life insurance or some other source
of income exempt by statute or judicial doctrine.
Given the minimal and somewhat cryptic statutory
definition
of
income,
it was perhaps
inevitable
that the United States
Supreme
Court would
be called upon to provide
further clarification of the con-
cept of income very early in the history
of the new tax. ln Eisner
v.
Macomber, the Supreme Court struggled
with the concept, declaring in
1920 that "income may be defined
as the
gain
derived from labor, from
capital,
or from
both
combined.o"t
In this statement, the Court
(proba-
bly unintentionally) considerably
narrowed the constitutional and stat-
utory definition
of income
as it strongly implied that absent the contri-
bution of labor or capital, a gain would not be included in income.
Such an
interpretation would
leave vast
categories
of "gain" out of the
statutory scheme,
and
hence,
out of the
reach
of the federal tax collec-
tor. In construing
the statute so narrowly, the Court introduced
addi-
tional
confusion
into an already
uncertain
area'z and offered litigation-
minded
taxpayers a basis for disregarding the broad all-encompassing
statutory definition
of income
when
preparing
their tax returns.
le
U,S.
CoNsr. amend. XVI.
'?o
l.R.C. $ 6l(a). Thc 1939 Internal Revenue Code relied upon a somewhat more wordy
definition
of "gross
income" in section 61(a), while the 1954
tax code returned
to a definition
closer to that first used
in 1913.
r! Eisner
v. Macomber, 252
U.S. 189,
207
(1920).
ry See MlnvrN A. CHrnsLsrErN, Frornrl INcour TlxlrroN 7 (4th
ed. 1985)
("[C]ould it
be asserted that 'labor'
or 'capital'
somehow inheres in every human activity? The Macomber
definition
apparently
possessed
metaphysical
properties
which
made
it difficult
to apply
in an abso-
lutefashion....").
325
326 GEo. Mlsou INoEp. L. REv [Yol.2:2
From the practitioner's perspective,
this confusion was
a positive
development.
It supported aggressive
"reporting positions"
that would
exclude
from taxable income
accessions
to a client's wealth
not derived
from either
labor
or capital
(such
as
gifts)
and
invites litigation
over
such claimed exclusions.'3
It was not until 1955 in the case
of Commissioner
v. Glenshaw
Glass Co. that the Supreme
Court finally settled the issue by embrac-
ing the
broad language of the Sixteenth
Amendment, including virtu-
ally
everything in income. The
Court defined income as all "accessions
to wealth, clearly realized, and over which
the taxpayers
have
complete
dominion."2a
The
judicial
adoption of this
broad
definition also resolved
the issue
reasonably well
for purposes
of creating
an
administrable
defi-
nition
of income for the tax code. The statutory scheme is that
every
"accession"
to wealth is
presumptively
included in income unless other-
wise specifically excluded by statute,
and in some limited circum-
stances, by judicial
doctrine.26 The Bureau of Internal
Revenue
and
later,
the
Internal Revenue
Service, had always
adopted
this structure
2s
See, e.g.,
Bogardus v.
Comm'r,302 U.S.34
(1937);
Robertson
v.
United States,343 U.S.
7ll (1952);
Commissioner v.
Duberstein, 363
U.S.
278
(1960)
(donative
intent required
for non-
taxable
gift).
8' Commissioner
v.
Glenshaw Glass Co.,348
U.S.426,431
(1955).
26
Since the broad definition
of income was
adopted, there is little room left for judicial
exceptions to the
general
rule
that all "accessions to wealth"
are included in income. Howcver,
during the
years
of the Depression in the 1930's,
the courts commonly enunciated
exceptions to
the broad definition of inclusion in income. For instance, after outlining the rule for including
income realized
on the discharge of indebtedness-a
common occurrence during the Depression
when
the value of real
property
declined
severely, leaving
many mortgage
lenders inadequately
secured and
willing
to accept
partial pay-offs
of loans-the courts carved out a number of rather
dubious
judicial
exceptions
that are only recently
being
withdrawn
by the courts
(although
the
Treasury never
acquiesced in most of these decisions
from the first). See Kirby Lumber Co. v.
United
States,284
U.S.
I (1931)
(in
the majority
opinion, Justice Holmes holds that income
was
realized by a corporation upon
acquisition of its own debt instrument for less than face
value);
Dtt
sea Bowers
v. Kerbaugh-Empire,27l
U.S. 170
(1926)
(where
"overall transaction" was
a loss,
income not recognized
on discharge
of debt for less
than face
value); Fulton
Gold Corp.
v.
Comm'r,3l B.T.A.5l9 (1934) (reduction
in non-recourse debt
is treated as a basis reduction
rather than recognized
as income). Kerbaugh-Empire
and Fulton Gold have been severely criti-
cized by courts and
the IRS for years.
See, e.g., Vukasocvich,
Inc.
v. Comm'r, 790 F.2d 1409,
l4l4 (9th
Cir. 1986). Indeed, the whole debt-discharge
area is still not supported
on a firm theo-
retical
foundation, as evidenced
by the recent
bizarre
case of Zarin v. Comm'r, 92 T.C. 1084
(1989),
rev'd,916
F.2d 110
(3d
Cir. 1990)
(compulsive
gambler
lost
$3.5
million in casino
gam-
bling on credit and in settlement
with casino, he
paid
$500,000
of the debt-lRS asserted
that
taxpayer recognized
$3 million of income from cancellation of indebtedness). For
one of the better
discussions of Zarin,
see Daniel Shaviro, The ManWho Lost Too Much: Zarinv. Commissioner
and the Measurement of Taxable
Consumption,54 Tlx L. Rrv. 215
(1990).
t9941 IllusroNs or Tlx StrvtpLrErcntIoN 327
in litigation as the basic
framework
of the federal
income
tax even
prior
to the Court's adoption of a similar view of "income" in 1955.
In these and other early decisions,
the federal courts crafted a
practical
and administrable concept
of income for the new income
tax;
and
even as
the tax code
evolved and
provided greater
details of other
statutory definitions,
the definition
of "income" remained very much
a
question
determined by reference
to these early judicial decisions.
However, there still remains a sizeable
grey
area as
to what
amounts to
income subject to the grasp
of the federal
income
tax, even after de-
cades of judicial construction.26
The courts also
performed
the essential
task of drawing
the bound-
aries of administrative
power
by reviewing
the
governmentos
own inter-
pretations
of the tax statutes.
While
the courts
paid
all the usual defer-
ence to the expertise of the tax experts in the administrative
agencies
with respect
to their interpretation
of the tax
laws, there was little hesi-
tancy to find in favor
of taxpayers
against the tax authorities. Through
extensive litigation over the basic
issues
arising under the federal in-
come tax, the courts enunciated the broad
doctrine necessary
to fill in
the
considerable
gaps
in the tax laws
and
restrained
the tendency of the
government
to construe
the tax laws entirely in its own favor. In this
respect, the federal courts
played
an instrumental role in the develop-
ment of the federal income
tax.
3. Development
of the Tax System During the First Regime
During
the first
quarter
of a century
under
the new federal income
tax-the "first regims"-1fis statutory
framework
of the tax was
clari-
fied
by Congress, the administrative capabilities of the Treasury
were
expanded and refined, and the courts
acquired experience
and skill in
interpreting the tax laws. Likewise,
as the increasingly
professionalized
and specialized bar became more
familiar
with the meaning of the new
20
"Construction" has
been
defined
as the "drawing of conclusions respecting subjects that lie
beyond the direct expression of the text, from elements known from and given in the text -
conclusions
which
are in the
spirit
though not the letter of the text." FneNcrs LTEBER, Legal and
Polilical Hermeneutics 44 (F.H. Thomas
1880),
quoted
dn
William F. Harris ll, Bonding Word
and
Polity:
The Logic of American Constitutionalism,T6 Au. Por. Scr. Rrv. 34,40 (1982);
see
a/so
Frank H. Easterbrook, Legal Interpretation and the Power of the Judiciary, 7 Hlnv. J.L. &
Pus. PoL'v 87 (1984);
Sheldon D. Pollack,
Constitutional
Interpretation as Political
Choice,48
Utrrv.
Ptrr. L. REv. 989
(1987).
328 Gro. M,c,soN INnEp. L. Rnv. lYol.2:2
tax laws through experience representing
clients, a new
legal
specialist
was
born-the tax lawyer.2?
Thus,
the
first regime
of the federal income tax was marked
by the
gradual
institutionalization
of the tax system,
the
professionalization
of
roles
played
by the participants,
and the specialization
of functions
within the administration
of the tax system. This specialization in-
cluded locating the
power
to interpret
the tax laws through administra-
tive regulations and the
power
to actually collect tax revenues in sepa-
rate
offices
and agencies. During this period,
the basic
structure
of the
federal income tax was laid out and
the
participants
in the administra-
tion of the tax laws eventually came
to understand
the rules of the tax
system.
In addition, Congress
made
continual
refinements
to the tax
statutes based upon experience in administering the tax laws. These
statutory refinements,
along
with judicial doctrine
as it had evolved
since
1913, were
codified
in the
Internal
Revenue Code of 1939.'?t The
1939
tax
code included most of the
basic
features
of the
present
income
tax regime. The "expansive"
language
of the
first revenue statutes was
given
detail through decades
of statutory
amendments, administrative
pronouncements,
and
judicial review.
Yet, even after
paying
federal in-
come tax for more than a quarter
of a century, the new
tax code of
1939
struck
contemporaries
as
forbidding
and enigmatic.2e
During the first regime,
the existing administrative capacities of
the American
government proved
to be sufficiently
developed
to collect
the revenue from the income
tax. Because only l%o of the population
was
subject to the
individual income
tax in 1913, and only 57o subject
to the tax in 1939, there
was
no great pressure
for an expansion
of
1?
From 1905 to 1916, the American
Bar Association maintained a Standing Committee on
Taxation
which
participated
in the enactment of the Revenue Act of 1913.
The ABA's Special
Committee on Internal Revenue
was
instrumental
in the creation of the Board of Tax Appeals. In
1939,
the
ABA approved the organization
of the
Section of Taxation,
which
today
plays
a promi-
nent role in advising the Treasury
and
IRS on concerns
of the tax bar. For a discussion of the role
of the Tax Section, see Harry K. Mansfield, A Brief Unoficial History of the Tax Section
-
1939-1989,44
Tnx LewyEn 4 (1990).
'r Pub. L. No. 76-1.
20
No less
a distinguished figure than
Judge Learned Hand expressed these sentiments
with
respect
to the complexity
of the 1939 tax code:
ln my own case
the words
of such an act as the Income Tax, for example,
merely dance
before my eyes in a meaningless
procession:
cross-reference to cross-reference, excep-
tion
upon exception - couchcd in abstract terms that offer no handle to seize hold of
- leave my mind only a confused sense
of some
vitally important, but successfully
concealed,
purport,
which
it is my duty to extract, but which is within
my power,
if at
all, only after
the most inordinate expenditure of time.
Jerrrrs S. Eusflce, Tax Complexity
and the Tax Practitioner,45 Tt* L. Rrv. 7, 7 (1989).
tee4l ft-r-usroNs or Tlx SrupuRcerroN 329
administrative
powers
into the area
of taxation.so
Thus, the traditional
nineteenth century system
of administration-minimal state institu-
tions, organized by political parties, subject to judicial re-
viewer-predominated throughout the first regime of the federal in-
come
tax. However, the
gradual
development of the
federal income tax
system,
including the code itself and the collection system,
was radi-
cally and abruptly
altered by the revenue crisis occasioned by World
War I.
During the
fiscal crisis of the
war,
policymakers
learned
an impor-
tant lesson about the individual income tax-the amount of revenue
collected
can be increased
fairly easily through the tax system
with
only relatively minor tinkering and adjustments to tax rates and ex-
emption
levels. Accordingly, the wartime
crisis
for additional
revenue
led to higher
marginal tax rates,
thereby
transforming the nominal
structure
of the federal income tax into a highly
progressive
tax.82
Political scientist John
Witte has described the
impact
of World
War I on the development of the federal income tax as
follows:
The First World War had an important impact on the income
tax, rapidly
transforming it from a highly contested but insignificant
source of revenue
into a major tax. Rate and provision
adjustments
made over several
years
turned what was
almost a proportional
tax into one
with a highly progressive
nominal rate structure.ss
Despite the importance
of World War I on restructuring
the federal
income
tax,
the impact
of the
War proved
to be transitory. Even
during
the height of World War I, only a relatively small
proportion
of the
citizenry was ever subject to the federal individual income tax. In addi-
tion, as revenue requirements
of the federal
government
returned
to
more traditional
patterns
after the War, tax rates also
were
quickly
to Figures cited in Timothy J. Conlan
et al., Taxing Choices:
The Politics of Tax Reform 17
(
l 990).
8r
See SrnpnEN SxownoNsr, Burlprxc A NEw Aurnrclx Srrrr: Tsr Exprrxsrox of Ne-
rrour- AprralNrsrRArrvE
Crrrcrrrns, 1877-1920, 29 (1982) ("Together,
courts and parties
formed the
bulwark of the
early American state.").
tt The top tax rate imposed during World War I was 71% on income over one
million dol-
lars. Rosrnr E. Hrll & AlvrN RlausHrl, Txr Fnr Trx 20 (1985).
8r JoHN F. Wlrrr, THr Polrrrcs ANp DrvrlopurNr Or Tnr Fropnrl lxcorrlr Trx ll0
(
I 98s).
330 Gno. MsoN lNosp.
L. Rrv fYoL2:2
reduced
to pre-War
levels.sa
Furthermore, following
the War, the fed-
eral
government
actually ran
surpluses,
leading
Treasury Secretary An-
drew W. Mellon
on a crusade
for the repeal of the
wartime
excess
prof-
its tax.36
B. The Second Regime: The Transformation
of the Tax System
The critical need for revenue
brought on by World War II led to
dramatic increases in tax rates as well as the transformation of the
federal
income
tax from a "class tax" into a "mass tax" affecting most
of the citizenry.so
The expansion of the American administrative state
during the
New Deal had already established a conceptual and ideolog-
ical acceptance of public
administration,
paving
the
way
for the subse-
quent
expansion
of the tax administrative state during
World War II.37
During the War years,
tax rates and the volume of revenue
col-
lected increased
dramatically.ss
Similarly, the number of tax returns
filed by individuals increased nearly eightfold
from 1940 to 1945.80
From the
initial l%o of the
population
that was subject to the individ-
ual income tax in 1913, the figure had risen to only a modest
5Vo by
1939.40 However, this changed
dramatically
over the course of World
War II. Furthermore,
the
structural changes
to the tax code occasioned
by the war were not withdrawn following World War II as they had
been
after
World War I. The higher
tax rates
and the
expanded scope
of the tax did not return
to pre-War
levels, and they continued
to in-
crease,
although more slowly, throughout the
post-War years.
By 1950,
u Id. at 96; see also BLnrEv and Buxnv, supru note 12,
at 189-334
(account
of Mellon
plan
for tax reduction during 1920s, including legislation
that
reduced wartime surtax rates,
cstate
taxes, and corporation taxes in 1924, 1926 and 1928, respectively).
E5
Mellon, Treasury Secretary
undcr four presidents, played
the leading rolc in the return to
tax "normalcy." Under Mellon's long reign at Trcasury,
wartime debt was significantly reduced
and the budget actually yielded
surpluses
for eleven straight years,
cvcn as the wartimc excess
profits tax was abandoned. See Paul, supra note 12,
at 122-42.
While tax rates decreascd, thc
relative contribution of the income
tax to total federal
revenue increased during the 1920s.
RrcH-
enp B. GoopB,
THE INDrvrDUer
lNcoun Tu 2-3
(1976).
8"
,See C. EucnNp StEuEnLE, Trtr Tlx DEclonr How TlxEs Clur To Dorrrrx,rrr Tgn
Pust-rc Aonxpe l3 (1992);
Wnrn, supra note 33,
at 110-30.
The most comprehensive discussion
of the expansion
of the
income
tax during
World War II is
found
io Pr.r, supra note 12,
^l 249-
392.E?
See DoNlrp R. BneNo, Conponerrsru ANo Tnr Rur-E Or Lrw: A Sruoy Or Tnn Nn-
ttoNrt Rrcovrny Aotr,ttNIstnrnoN
(1988);
see also,
SrownoNnx, supra note 31, at 288-90.
86
See
Wtttr, supra note 33,
at l10-30.
8e
CoNLeN, supra note 8, at 18.
{o See Gooon, supra rl.ote 35, at 3.
19941 h-lustoNs or Tlx Srtr,tplrrrcerroN
as
much as 59Vo of the
population
was
subject
to the
individual income
tax, and that figure increased to SlVo by 1970.4r Revenue
from the
federal
income tax rose to 45Vo of all federal tax receipts by 1950,
and
by 1985, the
figure
had
risen
to 73Vo.a2
Thus, the great
impact of World War II on fiscal
policy
was
that
the federal income tax emerged
as the most significant source of reve-
nue for the federal
government
as both tax rates increased
and
more of
the population
became
subject
to the tax. The federal income tax also
became one
of the most
wide-ranging
and all-encompassing
of Ameri-
can
public policies,
affecting many aspects of social
and economic life
of the citizenry through
the public policies
built into the tax code
and
imposing
what may very well be the most burdensome
obligation of
citizenship.
Perhaps the single most important change
in the tax laws imple-
mented
during World War II that made
possible
the creation and ex-
traordinary
growth of the post-War
tax administrative bureaucracy
was the introduction of so-called
"withholding
at the source."ns
With-
holding
was
contemplated and favored by those
who enacted
the first
income tax in 1913, in particular
Cordell Hull (Dem.,
Tenn.),
Chair-
man of the House
Ways
and Means Committee. Supporters
generally
viewed
with favor the British system
of "collection-at-the-source,"
which imposed a flat rate on prescribed payments
and
was indifferent
to the income or financial status of the recipient, and thus,
was
highly
administrable.aa
Withholding
at the source was not actually
put into effect until
1943
pursuant
to the Current Tax Payment
Act enacted
during the
wartime
crisis for revenue.
Until this legislation, the individual income
tax was
paid
solely through
quarterly payments
of estimated tax for the
current
year.a6
The Roosevelt
administration
had been
recommending
ar Id. at 19.
12
Id.
4' See, e.9., Bunxnlu, supra note I 3, at I 5 ("Although the
withholding
statute traditionally
receives
only passing
attention
from most tax scholars,
its importance
in increasing
the basic
power
of the IRS cannot
be overstated."). For a discussion of the
politics
behind the enactment of
the first withholding
requirements, see PrruI-,
supra note 12,
at 333-34.
tt .See BL,rKrv
eNo
BLnrnv, supra note L2,at75,5ll-20. Proponents
ofwithholding at the
source also looked to the English
experience
with envy as
it raised significant revenue through
this
device.
{r This is still thc method of payment
of tax with respect to sclf-earned
income. .See
I.R.C.
$S
6315,
6654
(Law.
Co-op.
1993). Technically, there is no requirement to pay
such
estimated
taxes. However, therc are penalties
for the failure to make adequate
quarterly
payments
of one's
annual income tax liability, Absent these
provisions,
individuals
would
not need to make
any
in-
331
332 Gro. MesoN INorp. L. Rnv fYol.2:2
withholding
requirements in order to speed up the collection
of the
badly
needed revenue to which
the national
government
now laid claim
under
the
newly
expanded
federal income
tax.
The new legislation cre-
ated a new obligation
for payers
of compensation,
interest
and divi-
dends
to withhold
a prescribed
amount of income tax from the
payment
itself.ao
In addition to the introduction of withholding
at the source,
"information
reporting" requirements
also
were
created and imposed
upon the same categories of payers.
Later, legislation
was
enacted to
require the payers
of compensation,
interest,
and dividends to report
such
payments
to the IRS on an annual
basis.az Over subsequent
de-
cades,
withholding
and information reporting requirements
were
con-
stantly expanded through the incremental
tax policymaking process.
Information reporting
provides
the IRS with independent notice
and
verification
of much
of the gross
income
of most
of U.S. resident
taxpayers.
With information reporting
applicable
to the payment
of
wages
to employees,
remuneration
paid
to independent contractors,
in-
terest
and dividend
payments,
and even the gross proceeds
realized
from the sale of stock and securities, the IRS now
has
available to it
significant
information regarding the tax status of a significant
percent-
age of taxpayers. Of course, such information
is useless
without the
administrative
capacity to digest the vast, and potentially
overwhelm-
ing,
volume
of information
that the IRS receives
from
payers
with re-
spect to taxpayers. Computers
now
offer the IRS the capability to cor-
relate and match all the vast and otherwise incomprehensible
information
gathered
from these
payers.aE
On the whole, withholding
and
information reporting
greatly
changed
the posture
of the IRS and
the
income tax from a "self-assessed"
tax paid
on an annual basis by
the taxpayer himself, to one in which
payments
and a good
deal of the
come
tax payments
until April lsth of the following
year
- the
due date for their income tax
r€turn.
16
The
withholding
requirements, expanded
greatly
since introduced in 1943, are now found
in the
I.R.C.
at $S
3401-06.
'? These
obligations are
imposed upon
payers
under I.R.C.
SS
6041-50N.
{t The IRS computer system is hopelessly out-of-date.
Under the Bush
administration
the
IRS began
an $8 billion modernization
program.
Scott R. Schmedel,
Tax Report: The IRS Is
Reshaping,
Wlu Sr. J., July 7,1993, at Al. Such a measure is believed to be cost-effective.
Memories
of a much-publicized
breakdown in the IRS computer collection
system in 1985 still
haunt the attempt to rely upon computers to keep track of so much of the economic activity
subject to the income tax.
t9941 lllusroxs or Tlx Srrrrpr.rnclttoN
relevant
information is in the hands of the taxing authorities even
before
the taxpayer
starts
to prepare
an annual tax return.ae
With the introduction of income
tax withholding
during the war
years,
the Internal Revenue Service was able to enhance the enforce-
ment of compliance
with the tax laws.60 This trend continued over the
next
decades as computers
have
allowed even
greater
and more exten-
sive
withholding requirements to be imposed upon
private,
third-party
payers
such
as
employers, banks, and securities and brokerage clearing
houses.
With such
new
and
enhanced
tools
for ensuring
withholding
at
the source,
the Internal Revenue Service
has
emerged
as one
of the
most
productive
of administrative agencies.
Notwithstanding the
popu-
lar perception
that the IRS is somehow inefficient in its operations,
its
ability to administer a mass tax with over one hundred
million tax re-
turns
filed
annually
and collect nearly one trillion
dollars
of revenue
each
year,
is truly a miracle of modern bureaucracy.ot
If World War II helped
to establish
the federal income tax as one
of the most important fiscal tools of the American
polity, tax poli-
cymaking
during the immediate
post-War
era
followed much
the
same
patterns
that had
prevailed
during
the pre-War,
Depression
era polit-
ics.62 Furthermore, the post-Wat
era
was
a period
of relative
calm in
the political
world with respect
to the federal income tax. During the
entire
decade
of the 1950s, there was little notable legislation other
than the enactment of the Internal Revenue Code of 1954-essentially
a recodification, rather than a departure from current
law.6s For the
remainder
of the decade, the federal
tax laws remained
quite stable
and
constant with little significant
legislation enacted.6{
ao
Even
with the
powers
derived from
withholding,
information reporting, and computers, in
1993 the IRS still faced a backlog of some
$71
billion of unpaid
taxes. Tom Herman, Tax Report,
Wnll Sr. J., Jan. 20, 1993, at Al.
!o For an interesting,
if uncritical
portrait
of the Internal
Revenue Service, see John C.
Chommie, The Internal Revenue Service
(1970).
!r The IRS predicted
that it would
receivc nearly 113 million individual tax returns for tax
year 1992
by the end of September 1993. This represents a slight decrease over the prior year.
Daily
Tax Report
(BNA), September 28, 1993,
G-3.
Nearly one trillion
dollars was
collected for
tax year
1988.
BunNH,c,l"r, supra note 13, at 22. The IRS'own budget is $7.4
billion under the
fiscal
year 1994
budget
put forth by the Clinton administration. Drrlv Tex Rnponr, June
10,
1994, G-4.
!r For a dcscription
of post-War
patterns
of tax policymaking,
see
Wnre supra note 33 at
I3l-54.
!E
For a discussion of the 1954 revenue bill, see
Wtttn, supra noto
33,
at 148-50.
6r
One
important
piece
of tax legislation enacted during the 1950s
was
the
addition
of Sub-
chapter S to the Internal
Revenue
Code in the Technical
Amendments Act of 1958, H.R, Doc.
No. 8381,
85th Cong.,
2d
Sess.
333
334 GEo.
Mnsou lNnnp.
L. Rrv fYol.2:2
The new mass income tax provided
the Treasury Department
with
significantly
more revenue and became the most important single
source of federal revenue. However,
to accommodate this expansion
of
the tax and the
rise
in tax rates, the tax administrative state had to be
augmented to collect the
revenue
available to the
government
under the
expanded federal
income
tax.66 While the traditional nineteenth
cen-
tury administrative state
had
been adequate in collecting
the
tariff, and
was
easily adapted to administer the early income tax laws,
the war-
time enlargement
of the income
tax required
a major expansion and
reconstitution of the federal tax bureaucracy to administer the
revenue
laws as a mass
tax applicable to millions of new taxpayers.66
A good
deal of the complexity
that invaded the tax code in the
post-War
era can be traced to this transformation of the income tax
into a mass tax and to the related
expansion of the tax administrative
state. However, the causes
behind the explosion in tax complexity in
the
post-War
era
go
beyond these factors
alone.
To understand the ex-
plosion
in complexity that has been
witnessed
since
the 1970s, it is nec-
essary to consider other factors
that have
contributed to the unprece-
dented rise in tax complexity.
II. Souncrs oF TAX
Corvrpr-Bxrrv
A. Economic
Complexity
The dramatic
increase in the
level
of the complexity of the federal
income
tax laws during
recent decades has not
gone
unnoticed.6T In-
deed, it has been a favorite
theme of tax academics,
politicians,
and the
05
See Cttotr,lr,ttE, supra note
50, at 24 ("The broadening of the income tax base
during the
early
years
of World
War II to embrace most
of the
nation's
wage
earners,
necessitated
the utili-
zation of a number
of new
and innovative collection
techniques.").
s The total revenue
collected by all levels
of government
in
the United States
was
$50
billion
in 1944 during the
height of World
War II; $100
billion
in 1956;
9500
billion in 1977;
and
$l
trillion in 1984. RoN,c,Lo F. Kruc, MoNnv, TruE, rNp Por-rrrcs: INvrsrurrr Tlx Sugsrorlnrrs
lNo At"tpnrclr Druocn,lcy 16
(1993).
67
Writing in 1950, Henry Simons elegantly lamented
the increased complexity of the tax
laws, but could offer only a vague
explanation for it and little hope for relief: "Simplicity in
modern taxation is a problem
of basic architectural design. Present legislation is insufferably com-
plicated
and
nearly
unintelligible. If it is not simplified, half of the
population
may have to become
tax lawyers and tax accountants." Srrrt',roNs, supra nole 5, at 28. See also Hlr-l and RlsusHrl,
supra nole
32, at 5 ("The current
U.S.
income tax system is a nightmare of complcxity.").
19941 II-I-usror.rs
or Tnx Sltr,tpt-lrtcnrIoNI 335
tax bar.68
However, the many explanations offered for the increased
complexity of the tax laws are less
than
convincing or satisfactory. The
problem
of tax complexity
goes
to the heart of what
is wrong with tax
policymaking
in the post-War period,
and thus, requires more than
simplistic explanations or eloquent lamentations.
The reason most often cited for the increased complexity in tax
laws is
the
purported
increase in the complexity' of the
"world"
in gen-
eral, and
in the
economy
in particular.
According to this common
argu-
ment, the tax laws
were
necessarily expanded durrng the
post-War pe-
riod in response to, and to cope
with, the
increasingly
sophisticated and
complicated
world of business, corporate finance, and economic rela-
tions. Purportedly, as business transactions became more complex,
Congress
was
required to modify
the income
tax laws
just to keep up
with the
new
practices
of business.6e
l. International Taxation
There is a good
deal of truth in the argument
that the increasing
complexity of business transactions leads to increasing complexity in
the tax laws. For instance after
the 1950s, American
businesses
pro-
gressively
expanded their activities in foreign markets
and
foreign
cor-
porations
increasingly
began
to do much more
business
in the
United
States.
This change
in the international
economic
environment de-
manded
adaptation of income
tax laws to govern
the taxation of mul-
tinational business transactions and corporations conducting business in
several
jurisdictions.
Accordingly,
the provisions
of the tax code with
respect to "international taxation"so
greatly
expanded beginning
in the
0E
For a discussion of the forces
pushing
toward
greater
complexity,
see
generally,
Stanley S.
Svrrey, Complexity and the Internal Revenue
Code:
The Problem of the Management of Tax
Detail,34
Lrw & CoNrrMp. Pnoss.
673
(1969);
Sidney I. Roberts et al., A Report on Complex-
ity and the Income Tax,27 TxxL. REv.325
(1972);
James S. Eustice, Tax Complexity
and the
Tax Practirioner, 45 Trx L. REv.
7 (1989).
os
See, e.g.,Wnre, supra
note 31, at 149
("[T]he U.S.
economy had
become
much more
complex by the 1950s,
and the rudimentary laws of the early
income
tax werc
no longer suffi-
cient.").
In a comparable
example,
Wildavsky
attributes the complexity of the budgeting
process
to similar factors.
Aenox B. WILorrvsry,
TnE Por-rrrcs or rxr Buocrrnny Pnocrss 8 (1964)
("Budgeting
is
complex, largely because
of the complexity of modern life.").
oo
Within the context
of the
U.S.
income
tax laws, "international
taxation"
has
a somewhat
misleading
usage, referring to the taxation
by the U.S. of domestic corporations and U.S.
persons
with foreign branches
and/or income
sources outside the United
States, as
well as taxation of
foreign
corporations and
individuals with U.S.
source income
gained
by conducting business and
investment
activities
in the United States. For an excellent and comprehensive three-volume trea-
336 Gro. MmoN INorp.
L. Rrv. [Yol.2:2
1960s.
Some of the most
complicated
provisions
to deal
with interna-
tional tax issues in the code
were
introduced during
the 1980s. For
instance, foreign
corporations conducting
business
in the
United States
must now confront extremely complicated statutes and regulations
which
require
them
to determine
their "U.S. source" income,ot their
"effectively connected" U.S. income,62 and their U.S. interest deduc-
tions.83 They
also
must negotiate the "branch
profits
tax"6a and compli-
cated economic analysis required
with respect
to so-called
"intercom-
pany transfer-pricing."66 There is little doubt that in international
taxation,
tax complexity caught up to international
business
practices
with a vengeance
of its own.
2. Tax Law and Business Forms
Whatever the initial appeal of the
argument
that the tax laws in-
creased in complexity in response to the increasing complexity of the
world,
the economy, or even life itself, it is not
entirely
convincing. For
instance, the
argument assumes that the
use
of new entities to conduct
tise covering all aspects
of international taxation,
see Joseps IsrNnnnoH, IxtgnNertoNer- Tlxl-
rroN: U.S. Tlxlrror or FonsrcN TlxplyEns eNo FonrrcN INcorur
(1990).
or See I.R.C. $ 861-62
(1986) (defining
income
from "U.S. sources" and income from
sources outside the U.S.). Specific
provisions
of the tax code
governing
the taxation of foreign
corporations and nonresident aliens are found in Subpart II of Subchapter N of the Internal
Revenue Code.
62
For
the deinition of "effectively connected" income, see I.R.C.
$ 86a(c)
(1986).
os
For example, the determination
of the
portion
of a foreign corporation's U.S. debt allowa-
ble as a deduction
under the U.S. income tax laws requires an allocation of world-wide
debt based
upon the
location
of the foreign corporation's assets.
See Treas. Reg.
S L882-5
(interest
allocation
rule)
promulgated
under the authority of I.R.C.
$ 882(c)(l)(A)
(1986).
Sea c/so I.R.C.
$ 863
(
l 986).
ot See
generally,
I.R.C.
$ 884
(1986).
o0
Intercompany
transfer-pricing is
governed
under I.R.C.
$ 482
(1986).
Spurred on by me-
dia accounts of foreign
corporations
grossly
underpaying their U.S.
income
taxes, the
Treasury
Department began to pay serious attention
to transfer-pricing
in the 1960s. A Srupy on IN-
rERcoMpANy PnrcrNc,
Notice 88-123, 1988-2 C.B. 45E,
at 6-10. Treasury
issued
a so-called
"White Paper" in 1988 on the
question
of transfer-pricing. A Sruov on
INrEncompnNv PnrcrNc,
Notice 88-123, l9E8-2
C,B.45E.
The White Paper
was
a radical departure from the usual at-
tempt by the Treasury to describe
and address every conccivable transaction
and
set of facts and
circumstances in its regulations. This paper
was
devoted
exclusively
to transfer-pricing.
Howcver,
after
publication
of the
White Paper, the Treasury
Department began the inevitable barrage of
regulations,
and many taxpayers objected to them on various
grounds.
The Treasury retreated
somewhat and issued
"simplified"
regulations in January
of 1993, Nevertheless, even
these
regula-
tions impose highly technical standards that must bc negotiated to avoid
having
the IRS recom-
pute a corporation's income, Treas. Reg. $$ 1.482-l through 1.482-2 and Temporary Reg.
$S
1.482-lT though 1.482-7T.
r9941 IllusroNs or T,c,x
SrupLrrlclttoN
business
led to the expansion of the tax laws to regulate
such
develop-
ments
in business
practice.os
This is contrary
to the thesis that Ameri-
can law evolved
and developed to accommodate
the needs and
interests
of the dominant economic interests of civil society-i.e., modern capi-
talism.67 The former implies
that autonomous
political
elites are capa-
ble of responding to attempts to avoid
the incidence of the income tax
by crafting new statutes
and regulations to cope
with such
develop-
ments in business
practice,
while
the latter argument
presumes
that law
develops
in conformity
with the needs of the business community.
It is relatively
easy
to find examples supporting
both sides of the
argument.
For instance,
in 1958
Congress
passed
legislation
that pro-
vided for the creation
of an entirely new tax entity, the so-called "S
corporation,"
for the express
purpose
of providing
business
with a new
"pass-through" entity as an alternative to the traditional business cor-
poration.sE
The S corporation
is strictly a creature of the federal
tax
code, and its creation illustrates how the tax laws
can develop to ac-
commodate
private
economic interests.
However,
just as often it is the tax laws that produce
changes in
business
practices,
as
well as
in state corporate
law. The impact
of the
tax law on business
practice
and state
law is illustrated by the creation
of another entirely
new legal
entity for conducting business-the lim-
ited liability company.so
ln 1977, Wyoming became the first state to
enact
a statute authorizing the organization of limited liability compa-
nies, and Florida followed suit
in 1982. However, as late as 1988, there
were
only a handful
of limited liability companies
actually organized
co
See, e.9.,
Wtrrn, supra note 33, at 149 ("To match the complexity,
the codc needed to
distinguish
between
corporations,
corporations
with income
earned
abroad,
partnerships,
holding
companies, and a wide variety
of tax-exempt and partially
tax-exempt
organizations. Complex
organizations lead to complex sources and flows of income and costs,
which in turn lead to de-
mands for different treatment.").
az
See, e.g., MonroN J. Honwtrz, THB TnrNsronMATroN or ArraEnrcltt Llw: 1780-1850
(1977);
and Tnr TnrNsronMArroN oF AMERTcAN Lew: 1870-1960
(1992) (evolution
of Amcri-
can law as reflecting dictates of private
capital).
6t Subchapter S (contained
in $$ 136l-79 of the 1986
Internal Revenue Code)
was
first
added to the tax code
by the
Technical
Amendments Act of 1958, H.R. Doc. No.8381,85th
Cong., 2d Sess. The provisions
were
not in the original House bill, but rather
were
added by the
Senate Finance Committee. Sea S. Rnp. No. 19E3, 85th Cong., 2d Sess., 1958 C.B, 1009. The
legislative intentions
behind the creation of this new taxable entity have never been
very clear to
the courts, thus making it difficult to construe the many restrictions and rules
governing
Sub-
chapter S corporations. Howcver, therc were clear statements as to the need to accommodate
the
interest of business
in some sort of corporate
pass-through
entity.
0o
For a discussion
of the benefits and problems
of using
a limited liability company, see
Sheldon D. Pollack,
Use of a Limited Liability Company
lor Conducting
Business in Pennsylva-
nia, LXIY Pr. Brn Ass'N.
Q. 142
(July 1993).
337
338 Gno. MesoN INpEp. L. Rrv. fYol.
2:2
under those
laws. Then in 1988, the IRS issued
a favorable
public
rul-
ing regarding the tax treatment of a Wyoming limited liability com-
pany.
Stimulated by the Service's classification
of the
Wyoming
limited
liability company as a partnership
for federal income tax purposes,
this
new business entity
became "hot" and
nearly
all other states
rushed
to
enact
their own
versions
of the statute.To As a result, the landscape for
business
and tax planning
includes
yet one
more
entity, as
well as all
the new interpretive
rules and regulations
now being considered by
Treasury tax experts
to distinguish
the limited liability company from
other
pass-through
entities-S corporations and partnerships.Tr
Here,
the
evolution of state corporate law accommodated
the
dictates
of eco-
nomic
interests and developments in federal tax law.
However, it can hardly be said, even in this strong case, that the
federal
tax laws developed to serve or even accommodate
private
eco-
nomic interests. Businesses and individual investors
already
had
turned
away
from the
traditional
forms
of business corporations. They
began
to utilize alternative business entities such
as
partnerships
and common
law creations, like the Massachusetts
business trust, precisely
because
of the
more favorable tax results
that could be achieved through use of
such entities. As tax lawyers came to recognize
the advantages
to be
gained
by "restructuring" the traditional
forms of business transactions
through the use of partnerships,
business
practices
changed to accom-
modate the federal income tax code. This suggests that tax laws
play
an independent role in shaping the development
of business
practices,
rather than merely reflecting
and serving the needs of private
capital.
The expansion of the federal
tax scheme
within civil society had an
impact
upon
how the economy developed
and contributed in its own
way to the increase in complexity of business
practices.
Thus,
the rise
in complexity of the tax laws cannot
be attributed solely to an increas-
ingly
complex economy
and
business world.
Rather, the tax laws them-
selves
contributed to the complexity in the business
world.
7o
As of September 1993, a total of thirty-frve states
had already enacted statutcs
providing
for limited liability companies. The
Limited Liability Company-An Emerging Business Form of
Choice,LXIY Corporation Guide
(P-H) P 18.1
(Sept.
15,
1993).
See also,State-by-State Tax
Treatment
of LLCs
Reviewed, Srern Tex Rnvrsw (CCH) (Oct. ll, 1993).
?t The IRS has not yet revised
the regulations
to adequately distinguish between S corpora-
tions and partnerships,
which are similar, but differ in important respects. This task has already
begun
with respect to limited liability companies. See,
e.g., Rev. Proc. 92-35, 1992-l C.B.
790.
1994! IrrusroNs or Tnx SrruplrncetroN
B. Tax Reform, Preferences, and the Rise in Complexity
Much of the increased complexity in the tax laws resulted from
the tax policymaking process
itself, rather than from the
external eco-
nomic environment. It is often the case that high-minded tax reform
proposals
end
up as nightmares
of complexity once
translated into reg-
ulations by the tax experts in Treasury.
In the wake
of the success
of
tax reform
efforts in the 1980s, it is apparent that many of the reform
measures adopted by Congress and
given
effect
through Treasury regu-
lations themselves caused much of the increased complexity in the fed-
eral income tax laws.
Consider, for example, such tax reforms as the
passive
activity
loss rules which
were
aimed
at eliminating tax shelters.
The
passive
activity
loss rules were
enacted by Congress to deal a death
blow to the tax shelter industry
once and
for all.72
The basic
idea be-
hind this reform
was
to prevent
taxpayers
from using
losses
generated
from "passive"
activities
(that is, tax deductions from tax shelters
and
other
passive
investments)
to offset
income derived from either
portfolio
investments
(dividends
or interest income) or earned income
(wages
or
self-earned income).73 This approach appears relatively simple
and
straight-forward, but looks
can be deceiving.
The
problem,
once again, was
that the
vague and overly-broad lan-
guage
introduced into
the tax code in the burst of tax reformism
proved
to be useless against the
planning
of tax lawyers. It again fell to the tax
experts at Treasury
and the Service to provide
through regulation that
which was
otherwise unattainable
through statute. Unfortunately, the
resulting
passive
activity loss
regulations issued by Treasury
are so
comprehensive as to be incomprehensible
to taxpayers, the
judges
who
adjudicate disputes
over the interpretation of the federal statute, and
even most tax lawyers.
Introduced in successive sets of Treasury
regulations,
the passive
activity loss
regulations already
amount to over
five hundred
of pages
that must
be navigated by any taxpayer
involved in multiple
investment
activities.
Indeed, the regulations require some forty pages
just to de-
fine what is meant by an "activity"-a vital enterprise
when it is
7r
The passive
activity
loss
(PAL) rules are found at I.R.C.
$ 469
(Law Co-op.
1993).
't Proposals
had been formulated
in the 1970s by Treasury tax experts
to limit the gse
of
artificial tax losses to shelter
other ordinary income. However, such proposals
were modest
ir,.
scope compared
with what was
ultimately enacted in 1986. The concept behind the
passivt
actir-
ity loss
rules
was
first set
out in legislation
in 1983
by Senators
Moynihan
and
Chafee,
and
later
was
reintroduced
in the Senate tax reform
bill.
339
340 Gso. MA,soN
INnsp.
L. Rrv fYol.
2:2
remembered
that the rules
generally
require
a taxpayer
to account
for
each such separate
activity.Tl
The increased
complexity
has
even
tem-
pered
the
enthusiasm
of those who
initially saw
the
passive
activity
loss
rules
as
the vehicle
to tax "fairness."76
Some
have
argued
that despite
the inordinate
complexity
of the
passive
activity loss regulations,
because
they successfully
shut down
the tax shelter industry,
the overall
effect has
been
to simplify
the tax
laws.76 whether
or not
such is
the
genuine
essence
of tax simplification,
the majority of taxpayers
have
never
had to confront
these
technical
rules
simply
because
they
do not invest
in businesses
in which
they
do
not actively
participate.
However,
for those who
do.
some
of the most
impenetrable
and
convoluted
regulations
await
them.?z
In much
the same
way,
the original
issue
discount
(OID) rules
which
were
intended
to prevent
tax avoidance
through
deferral
of the
payment
of tax78 and the infamous
Section
89 proposed
regulations
which
were
meant
to prevent
discrimination
in the use
of pension
plans
and other
tax-favored
benefits
by management
to the exclusion
of
workers.
The Section
89 regulations
imposed
complex
and incompre-
hensible
rules
on
employers
with respect
to qualified
retirement plans.?e
These
regulations
ultimately
were
withdrawn
by the Internal
Revenue
Service
in direct response
to the significant public
outcry
against
this
7' In an effort
to simplify these regulations,
the 6nal regulations
were
shortened
considerably,
purportedly
reducing
the complexity
of the
rules.
See Treas.
prop.
Reg.
$ 1.469-4.
7E
see,
e.9., Stephen
P.
Allen,
Fixing The passive
Activiry Loss
Rules,50
Tlx Norrs l4l9
(Mar. 25, 1991)
("The PAL rules
have
been
quite
effective in dealing with tax
shelters.
Unfortu-
nately,
they have
also
produced
a serious
side effect:
a substantial
increase
in tax law
complexity.
In making
the tax system
more
fair, congress
has
also made
it more incomprehensible.").
76
stanley A. Koppelman,
At-Risk and passive
Activity Limitations: can complexity be
Reduced?,45
Trx L. Rev.
97,
105-06
(1989)
("Notwithstanding
the length
and detail
of the
PAL rules,
they represent
a net simplification
of the tax system.
The success
of these rules
in
eliminating
complex
tax
shelter investments
has simplified
the investment
decisions
for
most high
income
taxpayers.").
Notwithstanding
the implications
of Professor
Koppelman's
statement,
it is
probably
fair to say
that most
of the
taxpayers
who
previously
wrestled
with
complex
tax shelter
investments would gladly
do so
again
if only
given
the
opportunity.
7?
As one commentator
has
put
it: "It is
now
three
years
after the
enactment
of the limitation
on
passive
losses.
And something
is
terribly wrong.
From
a simple
idea
to limit tax shelters
there
has developed
a set
of statutory
rules
and administrative
regulations
of immense
complexity.
The
complexity
of these
rules is
so
Sreat
that
most taxpayers
will
never
be able
to understand
them."
Richard M. Lipton, PALs at Three: what we Know, what ll/e Don't Know And wat ltlent
l4trong,67
Trxrs 715
(1989)
(emphasis
in original);
see
also
Richard
M. Lipton,
pALS ar Four:
Living with the Regulations,
68 Tlxrs 779 (1990).
7E
See infra notes 90-91
and
accompanying
text.
?o
I.R.C.
g 89 (prior
to 1989
amendment).
r9941 lllusroNs or Trx Srupnrrclrtou
"regulatory nightmare."80 These
and other
regulatory nightmares
were
originally
conceived
of as reforms and implemented to prevent
abuses
of the tax laws. However, they ultimately
increased the complexity of
the tax laws to the point where they nearly become
dysfunc-
tional-where taxpayers and the Service can
no longer
understand or
apply the tax laws.sr
The
congressional tendency to implement
more and more domestic
policy
through so-called
"tax expenditures" is another significant devel-
opment in tax policymaking
that accounts
for a large
portion
of the
increased magnitude
and complexity of the tax laws. Paul
McDaniel
has
written
that "the use of tax expenditures constitutes
the single big-
gest
cause of complexity in our tax system."82
This may
be
something
of an
overstatement, but it is hard
to quarrel
with the
assertion that tax
expenditures contribute
much
to the increase in complexity of the tax
code.
Tax expenditures
have
been defined as
"those
revenue losses
at-
tributable to provisions
of the Federal tax laws
which
allow a special
exclusion, exemption, or
deduction
from
gross
income or which provide
a special credit, a preferential
rate of tax, or a deferral of tax
liability."83
By
the
1960s it was common
practice
to use tax credits and
prefer-
ences to implement
social and economic
policy.
The effort to incorpo-
rate so much domestic
policy
into the tax code requires tax
policymak-
ers to draw ever more subtle distinctions
between those taxpayers and
transactions intended to qualify
for the tax benefits and those
who
are
perceived
to be abusing these
provisions.
These distinctions inevitably
require increasingly complicated
rules and regulations. Social
policies
as diverse
as encouraging
"research
and
development"sa
and
low in-
60
Pub.
L. No. 101-40,
$ 203
(1989)
repealed I.R.C.
$ 89. See also Elin Rosenthal, Seaion
89 Foes Unimpressed
by Treasury's Attempts
at Compassion,42Te,x NorEs 528
(1989);
Elin
Rosenthal, Sobering
Thoughts Intrude on Eulogy of Section
89, 45 Tax Notes 930
(1989).
6t The tax laws become
dysfunctional when
they become unadministrable, and thus, no
longer raise sufficient
revenue due to the inability of even
well-intentioned taxpayers
to comply
with
them.
62
Paul McDaniel, Federal Income Tax Simplification: The Political Process, 34 Trx L.
Rrv.27 (1978).
18
The Congressional
Budget and Impoundment
Act,
Pub. L. No. 93-344,
$ 3(a)(3),88
Stat.
298,299
(1974).
For
a comprehensive discussion
of the dynamics
of the
political process
of legis-
lating
tax expenditures, see
SrlNr,ny S. Sunnny, Prruwrys ro Trx REnonu:
Tur CoNcrpr or
T,rx ExpENorrunEs
(1973);
SreNr,sy S. Sunnsy & Plul R. McDeNrnr-, Trrx ExpeNprrunns
(1985);
JoxN F. Wrrre, Tnr Polrrrcs eNo DsvEr-oprr{ENT oF
rHE
Frprnll lNcorlrr
Tlx, Chs.
14 and l5 (1985);
Josrps A. Ppcsrrmr.r, FrpEnll Trx Por-rcy 355-63
(1987).
E{
I.R.C.
$ 174
(Law.
Co-op. 1993),
34r
342 Gro. MmoN INnrp. L. Rsv. [Yol.2:2
come housingE6
through tax credits,
and
providing
deductions for chari-
table contributionsso all contribute in their own
way to increasing the
burden
imposed by the tax code.
While tax reformists have
attacked the use
of the tax system to
implement
policy,
congressmen find the use of tax incentives highly
conducive
to satisfying their own needs as electoral creatures. Even the
wholesale
assault on tax expenditures launched
through the Tax Re-
form Act of 1986, as radical
a departures
from traditional tax poli-
cymaking as that represented, made
only a dent in the
complexity
re-
sulting
from these
provisions.
As the traditional tax policymaking
has
reasserted
itself
since 1986, the use of tax
expenditures
to make
policy
has increased again, thereby
assuring that tax complexity
will remain
a
salient
feature
of the federal
income tax for the foreseeable future.
C. Economic Analvsis
in the Tax Code
The tax code
also
has
grown
in complexity as policymakers
and
the tax experts in the Treasury
Department became
increasingly
so-
phisticated
in perfecting
the underlying concepts of the income tax.
This is especially the case
with respect
to purifying and refining
the
statutory
definition
of income. The federal
income tax rests
upon the
concept of taxing
income
received
or accrued
during
the taxable
year.87
As the
tax experts
have
become more
adept at defining
taxable
income
in economic terms, statutory
provisions
have become more complicated.
Economic analysis has
been
introduced
into the tax code in order to
eradicate
perceived
abuses
of the tax rules
(i.e.,
avoidance of tax) by
those taxpayers
who themselves
understand how to manipulate
eco-
nomic concepts
to their own advantage.
The new
"economic provisions"
introduced in the 1980s
contrib-
uted some of the most
complicated rules to the
tax code. For instance,
taxpayers once could
purchase
so-called
"zero
coupon" bonds or other
corporate debt obligations and defer the receipt and taxation of the
"interest"
payable
on such obligations
until the date of maturity
(or
redemption).""
Such deferral is viewed
as unwarranted from the
per-
tc I.R.C.
$ 42
(Law.
Co-op. 1993).
to I.R.C.
$ 170
(Law.
Co-op. 1993).
tI See, e.g., Treas.
Reg.
$ 1.4a1-l(a)
(each
taxable
year
is
a separate unit
for
tax accounting
purposes).
8t For a cash basis taxpayer, the interest income would
not be taxed until actual or construc-
tive receipt.
See Treas. Reg.
$ 1.451-l(a).
19941 IllusroNs or Tlx SruplrnclttoN
spective of the Haig-Simons definition of incometo in that the
debtholder's economic
position
has
been
enhanced over the course of
the year
as much as
if the interest
had actually
been
paid,
especially
where the issuer
is in sound financial
condition
and there is no reason
to question
its ability to satisfy
the obligation
to pay the accrued un-
paid
interest at maturity.
Accordingly the original issue discount
(OID) rules
were
intro-
duced in the 1980s,
refining
prior efforts to control this deferral of in-
come
recognition.oo The OID rules
impose taxation
on the interest
(and
allow
for a related deduction to the payer)
based
upon the concept of
the economic accrual of the
interest
rather than
upon its actual receipt.
This may be sound
policy if the sole objective
of the tax laws is to
ensure that taxable
income replicates economic
income.
However, the
OID rules introduced an extraordinary
level of complexity into the tax
laws by adding
the economic accrual concept.
If simplicity in the tax
code is respected as one of the
goals
of tax policymakers,
statutes such
as the OID provisions
must be considered a mixed blessing."
Another
example
of how the introduction of economic analysis
into
the tax code contributed to an increase
in the complexity of the tax
laws was found in the campaign against
"tax arbitrage"
waged
during
the 1980s.e2 The simplest example of tax arbitrage arises
when
an
in-
vestor
borrows
in order to invest in a tax-exempt
municipal bond.
Under
prior
tax law, the investor could deduct all of the
interest
paid
to
carry such a tax-preferred investment,
while
the interest
income
paid
60
"Personal income may
be
defined
as the algebraic
sum of (l) the market
value
of rights
exercised in consumption
and
(2) the
change
in the
value of rights exercised in consumption be-
tween the beginning and end of the
period
in question."
Henry C. Simons, Personal
Income Tax:
The Defnition
of Income
as
a Problem
of Fiscal Policy 50
(1938).
This "economic" definition of
income formulated by Henry Simons,
but generally
referred to as the Haig-Simons definition of
income
in deference to economist Robert Haig's
earlier
contribution,
posits
that economic income
is the sum
of the accumulation of wealth
and consumption over
whatever
period
of time is
adopted
for purposes
of measurement. For a discussion
of the Haig-Simons definition of income, sec
Rich-
ard B. Goode,
The Economic
Defnition of Income, in CoupnnHENsrvr
lxcorvrE TlxrrroN l-36
(Joseph
A. Pechman, ed. 1977).
e0
The
original issue discount rules
arc found at I.R.C.
S$ 1271-75.
or The Treasury regulations interpreting the
OID rules are
441
pages
long and utilize ex-
tremely complicated
economic concepts. In some cases it requires a computer
to
perform
the com-
putations
required
under the
regulations.
er Tax arbitrage involves taking advantage of the
differential rate of return on investments
arising solely
from the different tax treatment
of different sources of income. .9ee EucrNn C.
Srrurue, Tlx DEcloE: How T,c,xEs
Clur ro DourNerr rnr PusLtc AceNol,30-33 (1992);
David J. Shakow,
Confronting
the Problem
of Tax Arbitrage,4S
Ttx L. REv.
I (1987).
343
344 Gno. MsoN lNonp.
L. Rnv fYol.
2:2
on
the investment
would
be
exempt from income
tax.e3
The result could
be
a profit
derived solely from the differential
created by the tax code
itself.
While
this
particular
simple
version
of tax arbitrage
is now disal-
lowed under the tax code,ea other forms
still remain
part of standard
tax planning.
For instance, investments
in IRAs, Keogh
plans, qualified
ERISA plans,
and deductions for home
mortgage
interest involve
tax
arbitrage opportunities available to most
taxpayers.ed
Each
of the provisions
that creates such an arbitrage opportunity
is really nothing more than a tax preference
enacted to encourage
tax-
payers
to move their capital
into favored
activities. Tax complexity re-
sults
when economic-minded reformers introduce
provisions
to the tax
laws
in order to limit the ability of taxpayers to benefit
from the tax
preferences
that generate
arbitrage opportunities.
D. "Back-Stop" Tax Reform
As Congress has relied more
and more on
tax preferences
to make
public policy,
it also has
been
forced
to adopt other
reform measures
(such
as those that govern
tax arbitrage and bond discount in original
issues)
precisely
to close the "leaks" in the tax base and prevent
the
"abuses"
attributable to over-use of such
tax preferences.
In such in-
stances, tax policymakers
can be seen
as
rectifying
their own
poor
judg-
ment
and
excess
generosity
in enacting
too
many tax preferences
in the
first place.
Charles Mclure has
referred
to measures designed to limit
the use
of tax preferences
as "back-stop"
provisions
intended
to "pre-
vent the abuse of tax preferences
andfor the appearance of inequity
Through back-stop reforms,
the tax laws necessarily become even
more complicated
as
new
provisions
are introduced today to limit the
es
I.R.C.
$ 265
(Law.
Co-op. 1993), added to the tax code in 1954,
was
enacted to prevent
such a result by disallowing
the interest expcnse incurred
to acquire or "carry" tax-exempt
obligations.
x This form of tax arbitrage is prohibited
by I.R.C. $ 265. Municipal governments
used to
engage
in the
reverse
of this transaction.
They borrowed at interest rates below market rates
(on
account of the
interest-free
treatment
afforded
such interest
under I.R.C.
$ 103) and reinvesting
the bond
proceeds
in higher
yielding
markets,
with
the interest income exempt
under I.R.C.
$ I l5
(exemption
from federal income tax for "governmental
entities"). This practice
is now
outlawed
by
I.R.c.
$ 148.
e! Charles Mclure points
out that there
are now more than a half dozen
different
types of
"interest" in the tax code and
various
tracing rules designed to distinguish
one
form from another
for tax purposes.
Mclunr, supra note 5, at 63.
so
Id. at 43.
tee4) ILr-usroNs or T,c,x
SlupurtcnrtoN 345
applicability of yesterday's
tax preferences.
The incremental
poli-
cymaking
process
that generates
tax preferences
is generally
incapable
of such
a radical step as
abandoning them altogether,
even once they
are denounced by the same
policymakers
as abusive.eT Incremental
policymaking
tends to produces
only minor
adjustments
to existing
tax
policies,
and
back-stop
reforms
are
highly compatible
with such a strat-
egy
of policymaking.
Perhaps the best illustration of how incremental
policymaking
is
conducive to back-stop
reform
was
the introduction
of the alternative
minimum tax (the AMT).08 Introduced
in the Tax Reform Act of
1969, the
AMT is a separate,
parallel
tax system to the "regular" fed-
eral income tax. It is an "add-on" tax intended to back-up or correct
for the inadequacies
of the federal income tax itself. This parallel
tax
system begins
with a comprehensive tax base in which deductions at-
tributable to those tax preferences
deemed to be most abusive are
added back to adjusted
net income.ee Under
current law, "alternative
minimum taxable
income" is subject to a two-tier
tax of 26Vo and
28Vo
for individuals. It was originally introduced as
a flat l0vo rate
and
in-
creased over
the course of the next twenty-four
years
of incremental
policymaking
by a series of back-stop reforms.roo
As the many
preferences
added to the tax code
have accumulated
over the years,
taxpayers have utilized them
to an increasing
extent to
reduce their overall tax liabilities. Not only is this all perfectly
legal,
but it is precisely
what the statutes
were
"intended"
to do-namely,
induce
individuals
and
corporations to engage
in those
economic activi-
ties or purchase
those
goods
which were
singled
out by Congress as
particularly
worthy
of subsidy.
The alternate minimum tax demonstrates
how the tax law lends
itself
to incremental
tax policymaking.
It was
politically
easier for Con-
gress
to adopt this parallel
tax regime,
publicized
as a reform, rather
m To be somewhat more critical, the back-stop
reform provisions
reflect a lack of integrity.
Measures that wer€
once introduced
as favorable to the enhancement of the public interest are
recharacterized
as abuses
when
taxpayers take advantage
of the tax benefits
previously
offered by
Congress. Examples include investment tax credits, accelerated
depreciation, interest expense and
the
possessions
tax credit under I.R.C.
$ 936.
ot The alternative minimum tax is found at I.R.C,
$$ 55-58.
s In computing alternative minimum taxablc income, the taxpayer
must add back deduc-
tions allowed
for purposes
of regular income
tax such as
certain
interest deductions, depreciation
and exemptions. See I.R.C.
$ 56.
roo
The latest rate increase,
from a flat 24% to the aforementioned
two-tier rate schedule,
was
implemented by the recently enacted Revenue
Reconciliation
Act of 1993, Pub. L. No. 103-
66, at $ 1320, 107
Stat.
416
(1993).
346 Gro. M,'\soN
lupnp. L. Rnv [Yol.2:2
than
to sweep the
tax preferences
out of the tax code altogether. After
all, if use of the tax preferences
to reduce
tax liabilities
was
the
prob-
lem, then
reducing or eliminating them from
the tax code would
be the
logical
solution.ror
As such, the alternate minimum
tax reflects the
worst
tendency
of
incremental
policymaking-tinkering with change at the margins
rather than confronting the
underlying
problems.
And once a provision
such
as the AMT finds its way into
the tax code, it is
virtually
impossi-
ble to repeal it other than in the enthusiasm
of a massive tax reform
effort such as occurred
in 1986. Of course,
even if repealed
in such
reformist's zeal, old provisions
have
a nasty habit of being recirculated
as the
next decade's reform. This was
true
of the
investment tax credit
which resurfaced only eight years after its most recent repeal in
1986.'0' Likewise,
incremental
policymaking
succumbs too readily
to
the temptation
to expand the scope of back-up reform
provisions,
as has
been the case
with the alternative
minimum tax, both in terms of ap-
plying
it to more tax preferences
and in increasing tax rates for AMT.
Because
of this expansion of the back-up
reform, more and more tax-
payers
now find themselves subject
to the alternate
minimum
tax, al-
though a high percentage
of them
apparently remain entirely unaware
of the tax or their obligations and liabilities
under this
provision.
Back-
up reform
provisions
have
once again contributed to tax law complexity
in that they have created confusing
statutes to which
taxpayers do not
adhere.
III. Tsr Tlx Gevrn
One
way
to comprehend
the
dynamics
behind the expansion in the
complexity of the tax laws is to imagine
the income tax
laws
as estab-
ror
Some have
suggested that the
problem
is "piggishness"
in over-using tax preferences
to
reduce
one's tax liabilities. The
alternative minimum tax is the kind
of solution
put forth
to im-
pose "selective
limitations" on such
abuse of tax preferences.
See Daniel
Shaviro, Selective Limi-
tations on Tax Benefits,
56 U. Csr. L. REv. I 189
(
1989). Determining
when
a taxpayer takes too
much
advantage of tax preferences
is
an entirely open
question,
and attempting to determinc
when
a taxpayer has over-used
tax
preferences
inevitably
results in one more set of complicated calcula-
tions which taxpayers
will be forced
to confront. The AMT has
produced
exactly
this result.
ro2
In his 6rst State
of the
Union on
February
17, 1993, President Clinton formally
set
forth
his new
economic
program
to Congress. This included a proposal
to reintroduce
the
investment tax
credit. The investment tax credit was
first introduced in1962, suspended briefly in 1966,
termi-
nated in 1969, reinstated
in 1971,
and finally abandoned
pursuant
to
the Tax Reform Act of 1986.
This
proposal
was
ultimately dropped
in the wake
of much criticism.
.See
Mortimer M. Caplin,
. . . And Drop Investment Tax Credits,
WALL
Sr. J., Mar. 29, 1993, at Al2.
r9941 Ilr-usroNs or Tex SruplrrrcnttoN 347
lishing a kind of game.'oe
The tax laws create
a vast edifice, complete
with rules and
procedures
that must be
followed
by those
who, for bet-
ter or worse,
are
required to play.loa
As with any
game,
different
strat-
egies
will produce
superior outcomes, and
in the course of playing
the
game
over time these
strategies
become evident
to the players
them-
selves,
and they
will adapt accordingly.
But the concern here is not so
much the
dynamics and
logic
of play-the subject
of game
theory-but
rather
with the development
of the structures
of the
game
and the im-
pact
of such
development on the rules.
Toward this end, consideration
of the players'
interests in playing
the game
sheds
light on why the
rules developed as they
did.
The
point
of the tax game
from
the
perspective
of the taxpayer
(or
tax lawyer)
is to minimize one's tax liability (or that of one's client)
while
complying
fully
with
all of the rules directly on
point.
Of course,
since the "rules" are really federal statutes buttressed by criminal
sanctions, a failure to play by the rules can result in significant fines
and imprisonment.106
However, notwithstanding
such
penalties
for fail-
ure
to comply
with
the tax
laws
("tax evasion"),
there is no shortage of
methods
by which taxpayers can minimize or avoid taxation ("tax
avoidance").
Indeed, it becomes
quite
evident
rather early in the career
of every tax lawyer that any business transaction
can be structured
in a
number of different
ways,
and different tax consequences
follow from
different structures for the deal; this is true notwithstanding the doc-
trine enunciated by the Supreme Court that substance rather than
form should dictate the characterization and taxation
of a particular
economic arrangement or transaction.loo
As successive
generations
of taxpayers and
lawyers confronted the
tax laws, the rules of the
game
became apparent
and the meaning, con-
ro3
This analysis of the tax system as a game
can be traced
to the seminal
writings
of Oskar
Morgenstern and John
Von Neumann.
See Tne THEoRy or Glurs nNo EcoNotrrlc BEs,qvton
(1944).
Among the first applications of game
theory to social science
were WILLIITU H. RIrEn,
Tnr TsEonv or Pourrcll CoelrrroN (1962);
J,c,rrrEs
M. BucseNr.N and GonooN
Tullocr,
Tnr Clrculus or CoNsnNr: Locrcel FouNoerloNs or CoNstltutroNlr- DEtrrocnlcv
(1962).
r0{ The fact that taxpayers are forced
to play the tax game
does not affect the strategies or
outcomes of play,
nor is it particularly
unusual that a game
is coercive. For instance,
William
Riker analyzed the dynamics of the competitive relationship between the United States and the
Soviet Union in terms
of an involuntary "two-person"
game.
See Rtrrn, supra note lO3.
to6
See I.R.C.
$$ 7201,
"1206,7343
(criminal
sections
for tax evasion
and fraud). See Shel-
don
D. Pollack, The Penalty For Tax Fraud Against A Corporation,
Tun Tex ADvrsER
464
(July
1992); Hrnny G. BrlrEn, Trx Fneuo,rNo
EvrsroN
(1983).
ro3
CIR v. Court Holding Co,324 U.S. 331,
334
(1945)
("The
incidence of taxation depends
upon the substance of a transaction. . . . [T]he
transaction must
be viewed as
a whole, and each
step,
from the commencement of negotiations to the
consummation of the sale, is
relevant.").
348 GEo. MsoN INonp. L. Rrv. lYol.
2:2
sequences,
and outcomes of particular
sets of tax rules
were
revealed.
Much of the initial "learning stage" of the game
was
played
out be-
tween
1913 and
1919 during the first regime of the federal
income
tax.
In any
game,
the
level
of play
will rise to higher levels as
players
fully
learn the range of moves
possible
under the rules.roz Furthermore, as
the
players
become
more
and
more sophisticated
in their play,
the
rules
of the game
also may be modified to counteract
and balance
the in-
creased level of skill of the
players.
As a result,
the
game
itself becomes
more and
more
complex as
it becomes highly institutionalized.ros
It is impossible to predict
a priori who will benefit
from an in-
crease in the complexity level of a game.
For instance, in a game
such
as chess,
the beneficiaries of the enormous complexity
are those
players
with the
greatest
capacity to foresee
the outcome of the
possible
succes-
sive moves of an opponent. In baseball, the
progressive
institutionaliza-
tion of the game
resulted in shifting the balance of power
among the
players.toe
In the early stages of the
game,
before the
rules
and
logic of
the game
were
fully revealed to players,
hitters
prospered.
This was
because
players
in the field had not yet fully "learned"
their roles,
meaning they had
not
yet mastered their play.
Accordingly, hitters had
what
today
would
be considered improbably high batting averages from
1900
through the 1940's. Thereafter,
players,
especially the pitchers,
became more
proficient
in their skills,
and
rules
were
changed
with
the
express
intention
of restricting
the success of hitters. One example
was
the raising of the pitching
mound which resulted in batting average
declines in the
post-War
era of the l950s.rr0
In the tax game
it is difficult to know
with much certainty
at any
particular
moment
who
is winning-the tax lawyers
or the IRS. The
dynamics of the tax game
appear to be that once some clever tax law-
roz
As every
child quickly learns, the range
of possible
outcomes for the
game
of tic-tac-toe
is
too limited, and hence,
play soon becomes boring. Likewise, checkers soon bores most players,
although, in fact, there
are millions of possible
outcomes in checkers
(as
opposed to tic-tac-toe). It
is
just that the
games
all resemble
each other, and thus, offer no
great
excitement.
'ot For instance,
the U.S. House of Representatives became
increasingly
institutionalized
throughout the course of the nineteenth century. The role of "rcpresentative" became morc
profcs-
sional, decisionmaking
became routinized and formal, leadership became hierarchical, and rules
became more
complex as the House became
progressively
institutionalized.
.See
Nelson
W. Polsby,
The Institutionalization
of the U.S. House
of Representatives,62 Au. Pol. Scr. REv. 144
(
l e68).
'oo
The following
argument concerning the
effects of institutionalization on baseball statistics,
in particular
batting
averages,
was
put forth by Stephen Jay Gould,
Losing the
Edge,
VrNrrv
Fltn. March 1983. at 120.
rro Id,
t9941 luusroNs on Tlx Srrr,rpllrrcnrroN
yer
recognizes a new maneuver
around a particular provision
of the tax
code, and uses
it successfully to reduce
the tax liability for a particular
type
of transaction, the maneuver
quickly
becomes known throughout
the tax bar and
the
IRS eventually learns of it.rrr
Thereafter,
new reg-
ulations and perhaps
even new
statutes
(the "rules" of the tax game)
are adopted, shifting the
advantage back to the taxing
authorities
for a
period
of time.rr2 As this
occurs, the
rules
of the
game
inevitably
be-
come a bit more complicated, and
the tax lawyers must learn to play
and
devise new
strategies under the new rules. The tax game
is
unusual
in that one
participant
also acts as the referee of the competition,
em-
powered
to write
new rules
to favor its own side.tts In such a game,
it is
not surprising
that the rules
grow ever
more
complex as the competi-
torf
referee constantly
rewrites the rules
to its own advantage.
This increased
complexity in the tax
laws
can
result
in greater
un-
certainty
when
the complexity of the
rules
of the
tax game
reach the
point
where
players
no longer
understand them, and hence, cannot
pre-
dict the outcome. In a variation
on this theme, it has
been
suggested
that a moderate level of tax complexity is desirable from the perspec-
tive of both the tax bar and the tax authorities.lra According
to this
argument, higher levels
of uncertainty increase the cost
of litigation,
and accordingly, increase
the taxpayer's interest in pre-trial
settlements
which
reduce
the tax lawyers' fees.
The
IRS,
too,
generally
favors mod-
erately high levels
of complexity which make for greater
uncertainty,
and impels
taxpayers to comply with the tax laws, or upon audit, to
settle their disputes
(thereby maximizing revenue for the govern-
Irr Because
the tax experts in the Treasury Department
and
the IRS generally
come
out of
private
tax practice,
these techniques
of tax avoidance eventually become known
to the taxing
authorities. This
should be seen
as one benefit from the
so-called
"revolving
door" between busi-
ness
and
government
officials.
Itt Examples
of such new IRS regulations
relate to the so-called "May Stores transaction"
utilizing
partnership
distributions,
the use
of the Section 754 election to step-up
basis
in partner-
ship assets in the context of a consolidated return, and the taxation of new complex financial
instruments
designed to take
advantage of the treatment of contingent interest under the OID
rules.
See, e.9., Treas. Reg.
$ 1.1275-4(g)
(bifurcation
of contingent debt instruments).
rr8
In this respect
the tax game
is analogous to what would
result were
gambling
casinos
permitted
to amend
the house rules in response
to success by gamblers
in beating the odds - for
instance,
by banning "card-counting."
Of course, state
gaming
officials can usually be persuaded
to make such rule
changes on behalf
of the casinos.
rr{ See Michelle
J. White,
Why Are Taxes
So Complex and Who Benefits2,47 Trx Norns
341
(1990).
A tax attorney in the
film made from John
Grisham's best-selling novel, THe FrnM,
(1991),
states
this cynical
view
as
follows:
"It's a game.
We
teach
the rich
how to play
it so they
can stay rich - and the IRS keeps changing
the rules so
we can keep
getting
rich teaching
them."
Quoted
by
George
Will, The Tangle
of Egos and Rules, NEwswEEK, July 26, 1993, at 60.
349
350 GEo. Mmon INoEp. L. Rsv. fYol.2:2
ment).rrd Presumably,
the
policymakers
who
create tax complexity, in-
troduce complexity into the tax code,
or at least
tolerate it, to enhance
the
Treasury's collection
of revenue
under
the income tax laws.
This kind
of application of game
theory to an
analysis
of the devel-
opment of tax complexity focuses
on
the conflicting interests of the
key
players
of the
game
in determining what
they consider
to be an optimal
level
of complexity
with respect
to the rules
of the game.
However,
such analysis
demonstrates
the limits in applying
game
theory
to the
tax
system. The
analysis
is
useful in explaining
the behavior of taxpay-
ers,
tax counsel, and the IRS in terms
of elucidating the economic in-
terests of the
respective
players.
In doing
so,
game
theory assumes
that
the
players
make decisions
based
upon a rational assessment
of their
own self-interests narrowly
defined in terms
of the maximization
of
their economic
positions.
However, when
this analysis is applied
to the
political
elites who
actually make
the rules of the tax game,
it breaks
down.
When
political
elites are
portrayed
as
"players"
and their
behav-
ior is explained
in terms of the calculation
of economic
and rational
interests, the
conclusion is that they
will be
revenue-maximizers,
behav-
ing as
"predatory" rulers.tto
Similarly,
a pure
economic model will con-
clude
that political
elites
will raise
tax rates
to "point
E" on the so-
called "Laffer" curve,rrT disregarding
the interests
of civil society.rrs
lrc Accountants
are
said
to benefit from high
levels of complexity
as
well as
it pushes
taxpay-
ers to seek
professional
advice in preparing
their tax returns. According
to one economist, for most
U.S. corporations with assets of less
than
$l million
(constituting
90% of all U.S. corporations),
the
cost of compliance with the federal
tax laws is significantly
higher than their tax liabilities.
See Arthur P. Hall,
Accounting
Costs, Another Tax, Wlll Sr. J., Dec.
9, 1993
at Al6. A study
by Professors Joel
Slemrod and
Marsha Blumenthal
has estimated
that
for 1992,
the total cost of
compliance for the
Fortune 500
companies amounted
to $1.055
billion, or $2,1I
million
per
com-
pany
- seventy
percent
attributable
to federal
taxation,
and the rest to state and local
taxation.
"" See Margaret
Levi, A Theory
of Predatory
Rule, l0 Pol. & Soc'y 431 (1981).
Levi
presents
the
general
thesis that "rulers
are
predatory
in that they try to extract as much revenue
as they
can from the
population."
Id. See
also, Or Rulr eNp RpvrNur 3 (1988).
rr7 The Laffer curve was put forth by supply-side
economist Arthur Laffer, a member
of
President
Reagan's Economic
Policy Advisory
Board,
to show that at some hypothetical
point
on a
curve
comparing revenue with
tax rates, revenue will reach
a maximum
("point
E"), and
thereaf-
ter decline
as tax rates
increase
further. See
FouNo,c,rroNs
or Supply-Sror EcoNorvrrcs:
Tnnory
ero EvtprNcr (Victor
A. Canto
et al. eds., 1983);
Surrlv-SrnE Ponrpolro
SrnerEctrs
(Victor
A. Canto
& Arthur B. Laffer eds.,
1988). For
a discussion
and
assessment of thc theories
behind
the Laffer
curve, see
Drvrn G. D,rrvrns,
Ulnro srlrns Tlxrs exo Tlx Poucv 6l-68 (1985).
"E It is an axiom
of supply-side
theory that revenue will decrease
as tax rates increase be-
yond
some
hypothetical
revenue-maximizing
pcak ("point E') on a curve comparing
revenuc
with
tax rates
(the so-called "Laffer" curve). At point E, revenue will reach a maximum, and thereaf-
ter decline
as tax rates
increase further.
For a critical
discussion
and
assessment
of the theories
behind the Laffer
Curve, see Drvrrs, supra note
l17, at 6l-68.
19941 IllusIoNs on Tex SrnaplrrlclttoN
Yet, it is clear
that political
elites
do not behave this way.
Such
rational explanations take into account only pure economic motives
such as revenue maximization and ignore all the personal
and
institu-
tional motives and interests
behind tax policymaking.
For example,
policymakers
do not want
to raise
tax rates
too
high
because they
will
have to answer to their constituents for the higher rates. In open
and
democratic
politics,
such as that
which
prevails
in the
Western democ-
racies,
political
elites
are
continually subjected to popular
controls ex-
erted through electoral
politics
and the open expression of public
opin-
ion. Arguably, electoral competition and public opinion imposes a
significant
degree
of popular
control over
political
elites
and renders
them accountable to the citizenry in some fashion.tre The interest of
political
elites
in maximizing
state revenue at the expense of overall
economic
growth
can be tempered
and
restrained by electoral and
pop-
ular pressures.
The behavior of political
elites forced to compete in
elections
for the right to hold office may be effectively checked and
restrained even
without
the electorate understanding the specific details
of this conflict of interest over marginal tax rates. Recent experience in
American
politics
suggests that sharp increases in tax rates can
provoke
strong
populist
resistance
that is quickly
translated
into restraints im-
posed on political elites through the mechanisms of democratic
politics."o
Likewise,
the
impact
of ideologies
(such
as tax reformism
and the
liberal
political
tradition itself)
on the behavior
of political
elites is left
out of game
theory. So while
game
theory does offer insights into the
dynamics of the tax
game
in which
taxpayers, tax authorities, and tax
lawyers
all participate,
it provides
little insight into how
and
why
the
tax game
developed
over time. Ultimately,
the political
elites
who
are
responsible
for making the rules
of the tax game
(which
account
for
rro The seminal statement of this view of electoral politics is found in JosEpH A.
ScxutrrRrrEn,
Certteusl.r, SocrrLrsrr,r, lr.ro DErrrocnncv
(Ch. XXII, Another Theory of Democ-
racy) 269-83
(1950).
Robert Dahl built upon Schumpeter's theme, arguing that elections
insure
that "political
leaders will be somewhat responsive
to the
preferences
of some
ordinary citizens."
Ronpnr A. Dnul, A PnnElcr to DEuocnlrrc TsEony l3l (1956).
Others have
suggested that
elections also create a sense
of legitimacy and stability that benefits
political
elites and the regime
itself. See, e.g., BrNlrrurx GtNsrrnc, TUE
CoNsEeurNcEs oF CoNsEm:
ElrcrroNs, CrrrznNs,
CoNtnol eNo Popur-ln AceurEscENcE
(1982);
TnE CrprrvE PusI.rc: How Mlss OprNroN
Pnomorns
SrArn Powrn (19E6).
'ro For example,
consider the
grass-roots, populist,
anti-tax movement that began
in Califor-
nia with Proposition 13. For a discussion of this anti-tax
politics,
see
Susrn B. HlNsrN, Tnr
Potttlcs oE TrxerroN: REvrNue Wrrnour RrpnEsruurrox (Ch.7 - The 1978 Tax Revolt:
Causes and Consequences) 212-50
(1983).
351
352 GEo. Mesou INprp. L. Rrv fYol.
2:2
the increased complexity)
are driven
by much more complicated mo-
tives
and
interests
than what is assumed by game
theory.
IV. Tlx Rnronu: Tlx SItvtpI-IrtcenoN?
A. The Consumption
Tax: Changing the Tax Game?
Notwithstanding the many significant efforts to reform the tax
laws over the course of the
past
decades,
the tax code
has only become
more complex and confusing. Such
"innovations"
as the alternative
minimum tax only add to the complexity of the tax
law
without
really
addressing the underlying
factors
behind the perceived problems.r2r
The result is that the problems
of the old system are preserved
while
new
problems
are created as the
reform
provisions
are
inadequately in-
tegrated
into
the
present
tax regime.
While incremental
policymaking
so often results
in back-stop
re-
forms that clutter the tax code
with
ever
greater
complexity,
the lesson
of 1986 is that
occasionally
an extraordinary
political
coalition can suc-
ceed
in breaking
out of the pattern
of incrementalist
policymaking.
Such
radical departures from "politics
as usual" and
incrementalism
are rare in tax policymaking.
Indeed,
the 1986
Act may be
the only
example
in our experience.r22
But, as the tax code
becomes more com-
plex
and cumbersome, it may eventually reach
the
point where
the tax
system can no longer raise revenue
efficientlyrze and
compliance
with
'2r Sae discussion supra
part III.D.
t22
See,
e.g., Srrurnlr, supra note
36, at I ("By mid-1984, analysis and
debate on major
tax
reform was
underway, culminating
in the Tax Reform Act of 1986-the most
comprehensive
reform of U.S. tax
laws ever
undertaken."); John F. Witte,
The Tax
Reform Act of 1986: A New
Era in Tax Politics? 19 AMERTcAN Polrrrcs
Quenrnnlv
438,441
(Oct.
l99l) ("TRA can only
be viewed
as a remarkable legislative accomplishment
and
by far the most
radical
example of
peacetime
tax reform in history."); Daniel Shaviro, Beyond Public
Choice
and Public Interest: A
Study of the Legislative Process as lllustrated by Tax Legislation in the 1980s,139
U. Pr. L.
Rrv. l, 5 (Nov. 1990)
("[T]he 1986 Act was
the all-time leading example
of tax reform.").
rrt Increasing
complexity and
the inability
to simplify the tax laws may
eventually
result in
some form of system failure:
Because of the scope of tax reduction
provisions
and the complexity of the code, it is
doubtful . . . that the income tax can meet
potential
revenue needs in the future .
[or] that
it can
be
"reformed"
to expand the tax base and/or simplify the
system. Thus,
the radical nature
of change over time and the inability of the system
to resist change
create a policy
morass that is perpetuated
by its own structure.
'\Nnrt, supra note
33,
at 20. Even if Witte was
overly
pessimistic
in his
assessment of reform
efforts to expand the tax base, he was
correct in viewing the complexity
of the tax code
as a
19941 ILlusroNs or Tex Sur,rplrrrcnrror.r 353
the tax laws
will
decline.t" Such
developments could increase
pressures
for a radical restructuring
of the tax code.
As the legitimacy
and revenue-raising
capacity of the federal in-
come tax have
been
questioned
over the past
decades, there
has
been
considerable
interest
in abandoning
the
federal income
tax scheme
alto-
gether
in favor
of an alternative
tax system. This
sentiment
is reflected
in academic
proposals
for various forms
of a consumption tax. Dump-
ing the federal income tax in favor
of a national consumption
tax would
be the
ultimate
form of tax "reform" - abandoning all the tax expendi-
tures, back-stop reforms and special interest
provisions
accummulated
over the course of the eighty-year history
of the
income
tax. Addition-
ally, such a radical
change
would
have a major
impact on the practic-
ing bar.
A good
deal of the expertise of the tax bar gained
from eight
decades of experience
under the federal income
tax would
be negated
as a new tax game,
complete
with its own
rules
and dynamics,
took
its
place.
While there
is little likelihood
that the federal income
tax
will
be
abandoned soon, or even that
a national consumption
tax
will be intro-
duced as a supplement
to the income
tax, such
proposals
are no longer
matters of mere
speculation among
tax academics. The consumption
tax has
emerged on the political
agenda.r26
The primary argument of proponents
of a consumption tax rests
upon the assertion that there
are advantages to be derived from
taxing
consumption rather
than income.
The notion
is that the present
tax
regime
taxes
"income,"
including
the return
on investment capital and
thereby creates disincentives
for savings and incentives
for consump-
tion. This
taxation of savings, it is argued, is unwanted in an economy
that on one hand depends
upon
capital
formation
from the investment
of savings and simultaneously
saves
relatively little. This is not
a new
observation.'26
However,
the appeal
of the argument
has
increased in
potential
cause of system
failure. A four trillion
dollar national debt is
one
good
indicator
that the
tax system
is already reaching
that point.
ua There
is merit in the argument that
the
increased
complexity of the tax laws has resulted
in less compliance,
and hence
less
revenue
for the Treasury.
See, e.g., Eugene Carlson, Tax Com-
pliance
by Small Businesses
Eroded in the'80s, Wrll Sr. J., June
27,1991, at B-2,
(quoting
former I.R.S.
Commissioner
Fred T. Goldberg,
Jr. from testimony
before the House:
"We believe
that most
noncompliance is
unintentional. Much
of it is due to the complexity of the tax laws.").
r35
Numerous
bills have
been
in the
works
for
the introduction of a national consumption
tax.
None
have actually
been reported out of the
House Ways and Means Committee for a vote on the
floor of the House.
rrc.See,
a.9., Tnouls HoBBEs, LrvtlrrrlN Plnr II, chap.30 (1651):
"For what
reason is
there, that he
which
laboreth
much, and sparing
the fruits of his labor, consumeth
little, should be
354 Gro. MesoN lNprp. L. REv lYol.2:2
recent decades as the U.S. economy has failed
to achieve satisfactory
levels
of savings
and investment.
There are many
different
variations
of consumption taxes.127 Ex-
amples of different versions of consumption
taxes include excise
taxes,
sales taxes, the
value-added
tax (VAT) and expenditure taxes. Excise
taxes are imposed upon
particular
commodities
(e.g.,
cigarettes, alco-
hol, gasoline,
or such luxury items
as
yachts
or furs). Sales taxes
are
imposed
upon
sales
of broad categories
of commodities
or services, and
are generally
collected
by the seller.
The VAT is a common form of
national taxation in Europe, and also
was recently
adopted by New
Zealand and Canada
(in the case of the latter, in the form of the
Goods and Services Tax adopted in l99l).r'z8 This
type of tax is im-
posed
upon the value
added to a particular
commodity
by the busi-
nesses engaged in the various
stages of the manufacturing
process.
(Thus,
the tax essentially is imposed
upon the difference between
the
business's sales and its
purchases.)
The basic feature of all these
taxes
(sales,
excise
and
VAT) is that they
are ultimately
imposed
upon the
consumption
of goods
and servicesn rather
than on savings.
An expenditure tax is a consumption
tax that essentially is im-
posed
upon
individual
consumers,
rather than upon sellers or manufac-
turers. An expenditure
tax may be structured
following
a "cash-flow"
model in which
taxation
is imposed
upon
net
consumption of the indi-
vidual
over
the accounting
period.l2o
One of the purported
advantages
of taxing "consumption" is that it results in greater
"equity."rso The
notion is that an individual's
consumption
presents
a fairer base for
taxation than income.
Others argue
that consumption taxes are simply
more
"efficient"
with respect to avoiding distortions in the formation
of
capital
(an
argument commonly made
by economists).r8r On the other
charged, more
then
he
that living idley,
getteth
little, and spendeth all he
gets;
seeing the
one
hath
no more
protection
from the
Commonwealth then
the other?"
"? For a broad discussion
of various
forms
of consumption taxes, see JosEpH A. PEcurrrlN,
Frorur Trx Por-Icy
(Ch. 6 - Consumption Taxes)
(1987);
see also Nrcsol,ls Klrpon, AN
ExprNoIrun,E
Tex (1955);
EcoNoMrc
CnorcEs 1984
(Alice
Rivlin
ed. l98l); Drvrrs, supranote
117,
at 77-90.
rrt The Canadian
Goods and Services Tax, Bill C-62, effective January I, 1991, replaced
the
federal
sales tax in Canada.
lfe See William D. Andrews,
A Consumption-Type or Cash Flow Personal Income Tax,87
Hnnv.
L. Rrv. lll3(1974).
180
See, a.g., Alvin Warren, llould a Consumption Tax Be Fairer Than
an Income Tax? 89
Yrr-E L. Rrv. l08l (1980).
'E' This perspective
is reflected
in PncnmeN, supra note 100;
Joseph
Bankman
& Thomas
Griffith, Is The Debate Between
an Income
Tax and a Consumption
Tax a Debate About Risk?
19941 It-r-uslol.rs or Tex Stuplrrrcnuon 355
hand, some argue
that consumption
taxes
are "regressive"
since con-
sumption
by lower income
individuals
represents a higher
percentage
of
their
income than
it does
for wealthy
individuals. This
problem,
if it
indeed is a problem,
can be solved through an expenditure tax, which
can
include a progressive
tax rate structure.
In the end, however,
perhaps
the most significant obstacle
to
adopting an expenditure-styled consumption
tax is the great
difficulty
in phasing
out the present
income
tax and phasing
in a consumption
tax.ls2
The problem
arises
because
savings
previously
taxed under
the
old tax regime
(savings
in after-tax dollars) must be
identified
and
pro-
vided
with some form of exemption under the new
regime; otherwise,
these
dollars
would be taxed a second time if they are subsequently
consumed. Proponents recognize
such
problems,
but often dismiss them
as
solvable. However, if there is some extended
period
during which
the
new
tax is phased
in while
the income
tax is phased
out,
there
will be
two tax
regimes which
taxpayers must follow and
plan
around. Accord-
ingly, since a radical
break with the
past
is impossible,
the tax scheme
in effect during the transition
period
would be
even
more
complex than
the
current system since two tax systems
(three
if the
alternative
mini-
mum tax is counted)
would
be in place.
For this reason, the problems
from introducing
a consumption tax into an economy already
governed
by an income tax regime
are much greater
than those confronted by
nations
with developing, emerging
economies
that have never had an
income tax.r33 In such cases, the choice of a consumption tax as op-
posed
to an income
tax is considerably
more appealing. However, intro-
ducing
a consumption tax into
an economy having eighty
years
of expe-
rience with an income
tax would
be far more
problematic.
Because
of the
difficulty
in implementing an expenditure-type con-
sumption tax, excise-type
consumption taxes have been more commonly
used in recent decades
as
revenue
enhancers to complement the
federal
income
tax. For example,
excise taxes
have recently
been
imposed
on
luxury items such
as
yachts
and high
priced
imported automobiles, and
have been
proposed
for gasoline
and energy consumption. Such taxes
are more conducive to incremental
policymaking
and can be more eas-
ily grafted
onto the current
tax regime.
Does It Matter? 4'1
Tlx L. Rrv. 377
(1992).
Supply-side economists also
favor
consumption taxes
to the extent thcy encourage
savings.
r8r
Mclure identifies
transition rules as
one
source of the complexity of the tax laws. See
Mclunr, supra note
5, at 51.
18"
See, e.g., Charles A. Mclure, Jr. & George R. Zodrow, Implementing Direct
Consump-
tion Taxes In Developing Countries,46 Trx L. Rev. 405
(1991).
356
B.
Gno.
MnsoN
lNorp. L. Rnv
The Problem of Complex Tax Laws
[Yol.
2:2
While there has
been much
concern
of late
with a tax code
that is
beyond the ability of the "average"
taxpayer
to comprehend,
little has
been said to identify
precisely
the
problem
caused
by such complex
tax
laws.
Rather, it is simply
generally
assumed
that because
the tax code
is complex, there must
be a problem.
Such a simplistic
position
is powerless
against
the
retort
that most
of the complexity
of the tax code is seldom
confronted
by the avera1e
taxpayer, who
generally
files
a simple
Form 1040,
or more
likely,
Form
1040-EZ
(the
"easy" version
of the
individual
return for those in the
unenviable
position
of having
few
deductions
to claim).
Presumably,
if
most
of the tax law
complexity
affects
only wealthy
taxpayers
and
busi-
nesses
for whom
hiring professional
tax advisers is standard
procedure,
there
really is
no
problem
with
the many
complex
provisions
of the
tax
laws.
In other words,
complexity
is a problem
only if it reaches
the
middle
class.
To the extent
that the computation
of tax liabilities,
filling out
forms
and satisfying
the multitude
of filing
requirements
can be
simpli-
fied
for
a
majority
of individual
taxpayers,
as it was
by
the 1986
Act,rsa
even
while businesses
and wealthy
taxpayers
confront increased
com-
plexity, political
expediencies
very
well may be
satisfied. That may be
sufficient
to alleviate
the
pressures
on policymakers.
But there
is some-
thing
cynical
about
the view
that tax complexity
is a problem
only if
felt by the average
taxpayer
for it misperceives
the nature
of the
prob-
lem
of complexity
in the
tax laws.
Recordkeeping
is burdensome
and
confusing
for the taxpayer,
and
the ability of the average
taxpayer
to understand
the fundamentals
of
the tax law and
prepare
his
or her
own
tax return is a prerequisite
for
effective
tax policy.rsd
But the focus
of tax reform
should not be on
simplifying
the
preparation
of tax returns.
Simplification
of preparation
is usually accomplished
by eliminating
tax deductions
or imposing
r8{
see
sre,FF
on tuE JorNt
corrruttrEg
oN
TlxltroN, Grlrnll ExpllNltrop or tur Tlx
Rpronu Acr oF 1986
I I (1987)
(stating
that
"[S]implification
of the tax
code itself is
a form of
tax reduction.
. . . The Act reduces
the complexity
of the tax code for many Americans.
Taxpayers
who will use the standard
deduction
rather than
itemize
their deductions will be
freed
from much of the recordkeeping, paperwork,
and
computations
that were
required
under
prior
law.").
rEo
See, e.9.,
Deborah
H. Schenk, Simplification
for Individual Taxpayers:
problems
and
Proposals,"
45 T,rx L. REv. l2t, 166-6'l
(1989)
(discussion
of how
complex recordkeeping
re-
quirements
breed
noncompliance).
t9941 ILLustoNs oE Tex Srupr-rrrcntlox 357
threshold requirements
(such
as adjusted
gross
income) which most
taxpayers
will be unable to satisfy, and therefore,
they
will not be
per-
mitted
to use a particular
deduction.'36
Such a notion
of simplification
will be of little comfort to those
who
lose the benefit
of the deduction.
The reasons for tax simplification
go
beyond the
difficulty
of filling
out tax returns and computing
deductions. The
present
system of taxa-
tion has contributed much to the bureaucratization of modern life and
the
increased regulation
of economic life, for both individuals
as
well
as
businesses. Those
unsympathetic to the problem
of government
over-
regulation of business should recognize
that an overly complex tax sys-
tem also adversely
affects
individuals.ls?
The
tax laws
have a peculiar
impact
upon
private
behavior insofar
as they
do not
strictly
prohibit
particular private
action or conduct, but
rather establish a broad framework
of incentives and disincentives
through
which
private
activity is
subtly altered. The tax laws impose
a
superstructure
above and beyond
the legal framework
that prevails
under
the
liberal
political
tradition. For
example, a certain activity may
be entirely
"legal" in the sense
that there are no
prohibitions
against
such behavior. However,
under the tax laws, such
activity can carry a
price-the burden of additional
taxation. Tax liability creates a disin-
centive to transacting
one's business
activities
in that particular
form
just
as surely as if there
were
an outright legal
prohibition
against such
conduct. In this respect,
the tax laws seem
to be exempt
from a tradi-
tional tenet
of the liberal political
tradition-specifically, the rule of
law.tsE
The rule of law assumes that citizens are
governed
by clear legal
standards, and that
these standards
are enunciated
prior
to taking ef-
fect,
thereby
providing
citizens with notice
of prohibited
behavior and
t8o
For instance,
see the discussion
of tax simplification in SrEurnlr, supra note
36, at 136-
37
("Among
the major simplifications
achieved by tax reform was the elimination
of record
keep-
ing and tax calculations
for those no longer
eligible for certain deductions.").
re?
Speaker
of the Virginia
Senate,
Richard E. Byrd (1910),
in opposition
to ratification
of
the Sixteenth Amendment,
gave
the following
prophetic
warning
of the dangers of a national
income
tax: "A hand
from Washington will be stretched out and
placed
upon
every
man's
busi-
ness; the
eye of the Federal inspector will be in every
man's counting house.
. . . The law
will of
necessity
have inquisitorial
features, it will provide penalties,
it will create complicated machinery.
Under
it men
will be hailed
into courts distant from
their homes. Heavy fines imposed by distant
and unfamiliar
tribunals will constantly
menace
the tax payer.
An army of Federal inspectors,
spies and detectives will descend
upon the state
[of Virginia].
. . . Who of us who
have had
knowledge
of the doings
of the Federal
officials
in the Internal
Revenue service can be blind to
what will follow?"
Blerny and Bllrrv, supra note 12, at'10.
'8E
The classic
statement of the
principle
of the rule of law is found at FnrronrcH A. Hlvrr,
Tsn CoNsrrrurroN
oF Lrsnnry 162-75
(1960).
358 Gno.
Mnsow INorp. L. Rrv. lYol.2:2
the sanctions
attached to violations
of these
rules. Fundamental to the
concept
of the
rule of law is the notion that legal standards
of public
behavior
be
known, or at least
knowable,
by the citizenry.
To
the extent
that
the tax
laws are
public
laws
that similarly should
be
governed
by
the
principles
of the
rule
of law, the
excessive complexity
means that
the legal standards
enunciated thereunder cannot be
comprehended by
those
subject to sanctions
for a failure
to comply.
Perhaps the best ex-
pression
of the
case against overly complex and changing
laws is found
in an oft-quoted
passage
from James Madison in The Federalist:
It will be of little avail to the
people,
that the laws are made by men of their
own
choice, if the laws be
so voluminous
that they cannot be
read, or so inco-
herent that they cannot be understood; if they be repealed or revised
before
they are
promulgated,
or undergo such incessant changes that no man, who
knows what the law is today, can
guess
what it will be to-morrow.
Law is
defined to be a rule of action;
but how
can that be a rule,
which is little
known, and
less fixed?r8e
When the
level
of complexity of the law becomes
so
great
that those
who are subject to its sanctions cannot comprehend
what it is that the
law requires
of them, then the rule
of law has been abandoned as an
operative
principle.
In many respects,
this has become the sad state of
tax policymaking.
CoNcI-ustotr
The tax law should
develop through
judicial
construction of gener-
ally stated
principles
laid
out by Congress
in the tax
laws, rather than
through
"ever
more
complicated
prescriptive
rules"l4o
made
by tax bu-
reaucrats.
Unfortunately,
the tax laws
have developed
over the course
of the
past
decades
in entirely the opposite direction.
The tax code has
become a massive
and impenetrable edifice of rules and regulations
that describe
and
govern
nearly all spheres of economic
life and busi-
ness activity.
Reform legislation such as the Tax Reform Act of 1986
only
added
new complexity to the tax code
even
while
purporting
to achieve
!3e
THE FsorneLrst No. 62, at 381
(James
Madison)
(New
York:
New American Library,
ed., l96l).
r'o Peter C. Canellos, Acquisition of Issuer Securities
by a Controlled Entity: Peter Pan
Seafoods, May Department Stores, and
McDermotl,45
Trx Lrw. l, 14
(1991).
tge4l IllusroNs or Trx SrnrpuncenoN
an aesthetically
purer
income tax.
Provisions
enacted
in 1986 contrib-
uted
additional complexity
as
policymakers
were required
(first
in stat-
utes, and
later in administrative regulations)
to draw increasingly sub-
tle distinctions between what is allowed and
what is disallowed.
Such
over-legislating, aptly described as
"hyperleXis,"rrr
threatens to swamp
the tax code
with the accumulated
weight
of such
subtle distinctions.
One consequence of excessive
complexity in the tax laws is that it
periodically
stimulates demands for simplification of the federal income
tax.
Tax simplification has been championed by politicians,
academics,
bureaucrats.
and even at various
times
the tax bar itself. The issue of
overly complex
tax laws
also
raises
a number of important
philosophi-
cal issues that are beyond the scope of the immediate inquiry. Never-
theless, these
concerns
should be kept in mind as the impact
of tax
policy
upon the broader American
political
system is considered.
What
are the
implications
for domestic
policymaking
when
the tax
code becomes overly complex? What is the underlying
political
agenda
of those seeking specific reforms, such
as closing
loopholes or abolishing
tax shelters? How are individual taxpayers
(the
citizens comprising the
political
community) and their rights and liberties affected
by an al-
most incomprehensible
system
of tax
laws, regulations,
and
rule
by tax
bureaucrats? Are there limits
to how far the
tax administrative state
should intrude into
the
lives
of individual taxpayers
(as
well
as corpora-
tions and businesses) to raise maximum
revenue from the tax laws?
Or
to achieve an "aesthetically" pure
tax code?
These are the kinds of questions
that we will need
to collectively
grapple
with through
political
discourse as the tax laws increase in
complexity
and tax policy
plays
such an important
role in contempo-
rary American
politics.
t'! The term was defined
as
"a pathological
condition caused by an overactive law-making
gland." Bayless
Manning, Hyperlexis:
Our National Disease,
Tl Nw. U. L. REv. '767,76'l
(1977).
Manning wrote: "Statutory
codes, such
as those
in the fields ofcommercial
law and taxa-
tion, are
becoming ever more
particularistic,
longer, more complex, and less comprehensible.
We
are drowning in law." Id.
359

Navigation menu